Game Strategies in Luxury Auctions: Balancing Economic Efficiency
and Cultural Significance
Zixin Lu
a
Business Administration, Guangzhou College of Technology and Business, Foshan, Guangdong, 528100, China
Keywords: Luxury Auctions, Cultural Heritage, Game Theory, Economic Efficiency, Heritage Preservation.
Abstract: Luxury auctions represent a critical nexus between economic valuation and cultural preservationa dynamic
of increasing importance as global demand for rare artifacts grows, prompting scrutiny of their broader
impacts. The 2021 Sotheby’s auction of the Marie Antoinette Diamond Bracelets, fetching $8.1 million,
exemplifies this tension. Competitive bidding in an open format drove prices far beyond the $2-4 million
estimate, showcasing economic efficiency through heightened rivalry and bolstering auction house prestige.
Yet, the bracelets’ privatization by a collector and export from France severed public access, igniting debates
over heritage erosion and ethical stewardship. These market dynamics reveal a fundamental paradox:
Emotional overbidding further signalled risks of market instability. Proposed measures include export
restrictions to retain national treasures, hybrid auction formats to temper price surges, and partnerships with
cultural institutions to ensure accessibility. These strategies seek to harmonize profit motives with societal
values. As heritage items flood markets by 2025, this analysis underscores the urgency of reforming auctions
to safeguard cultural significance alongside financial success, offering insights into sustainable practices that
preserve shared history.
1 INTRODUCTION
Luxury auctions blend economic transactions with
cultural heritage, gaining prominence across global
markets. Research demonstrates that auction markets
for high-value goods, such as artworks and antiques,
have been steadily expanding due to growing demand
for rare and distinctive items (Ashenfelter & Graddy,
2003). Studies on competitive bidding emphasize that
open auctions, a frequent choice in luxury sales,
intensify competition among bidders, driving prices
upward through heightened rivalry (Milgrom &
Weber, 1982). Auction theory further posits that
increases in societal wealth and broader participation
fuel the growth of these markets (Klemperer, 1999).
Currently, luxury auctions feature a wide array of
objects—paintings, rare jewelry, historical artifacts—
each possessing significant monetary value alongside
deep cultural importance. Auctions extend beyond
simple exchanges; they are dynamic environments
where bidders employ game theory strategies, such as
aggressive bidding or precisely timed offers, to secure
victories. Auction houses, in turn, adopt rules to
a
https://orcid.org/ 0009-0006-0729-9326
optimize profits, leveraging bidder behaviour to their
advantage.
This phenomenon embodies dual significance by
substantial weight because it operates on two levels:
it delivers considerable financial gains to sellers and
auction firms while simultaneously shaping the fate
of cultural artifacts—whether they remain accessible
to the public or are safeguarded for future generations.
The growing concern that cultural heritage is being
reduced to mere commodities adds urgency to this
issue. For instance, an artifact auctioned off to a
private collector might vanish from public view,
limiting its educational or inspirational potential. This
study investigates how game strategies in luxury
auctions influence economic efficiency, defined here
as profit maximization and reputation enhancement,
as well as cultural value, encompassing heritage
preservation and public accessibility. As of March
2025, this question holds critical relevance: can these
strategies achieve a sustainable balance between
financial success and cultural stewardship? The
implications are far-reaching, affecting not only
market dynamics but also societal values tied to
186
Lu, Z.
Game Strategies in Luxury Auctions: Balancing Economic Efficiency and Cultural Significance.
DOI: 10.5220/0013821800004708
Paper published under CC license (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0)
In Proceedings of the 2nd Inter national Conference on Innovations in Applied Mathematics, Physics, and Astronomy (IAMPA 2025), pages 186-192
ISBN: 978-989-758-774-0
Proceedings Copyright © 2025 by SCITEPRESS – Science and Technology Publications, Lda.
shared history and identity. Exploring this balance is
essential to understanding the broader impact of
luxury auctions in a world increasingly driven by both
commerce and culture. These competing priorities
between economic gains and cultural preservation
necessitate a systematic examination of auction
strategies through dual lenses: game-theoretic
efficiency and heritage stewardship.
Extensive literature illuminates the mechanics of
auctions. Foundational studies reveal that open
auctions, widely used in luxury contexts, escalate
bidder competition by making bids visible, thereby
elevating prices through strategic actions (Milgrom &
Weber, 1982). More recent investigations highlight
how emotional factors, such as loss aversion or
personal attachment, often compel bidders to offer
premiums beyond rational valuations, particularly for
items with cultural resonance (Graddy et al., 2023).
Parallel research into luxury markets underscores that
prestige-seeking behaviour among affluent buyers
enhances auction outcomes, boosting both revenue
and the auction house’s standing (Keaveney,
Herrmann & Befurt, 2012). These insights
collectively demonstrate the intricate interplay of
strategies, psychological drivers, and economic
results within auction settings.
However, while economic efficiency is
thoroughly examined, the cultural ramifications of
these strategies receive far less attention. Studies on
antiquities markets caution that a profit-centric
approach frequently prioritizes financial gain over
cultural ownership, leading to privatization and
ethical dilemmas (Keaveney, Herrmann & Befurt,
2012). For example, an artifact sold to a private buyer
might be locked away and inaccessible to scholars or
the public, raising questions about its societal role.
Despite these warnings, few analyses integrate this
cultural perspective with game-theoretic frameworks,
leaving a notable gap in understanding how auction
strategies affect more than just the bottom line. This
study seeks to bridge this divide by exploring both the
economic advantages and cultural consequences of
strategic bidding in luxury auctions, aiming to
provide a more holistic view of their impact.
While extant research has firmly established how
game strategies enhance economic returns in luxury
auctions (e.g., Milgrom & Weber, 1982; Graddy et al.,
2023), significantly less attention has been paid to
their cultural externalities—particularly how bidder
tactics and auction house rules influence the long-
term accessibility and conservation of heritage
artifacts (Mackenzie & Davis, 2014). This
commodification risks eroding the broader value
these objects hold for society, such as their
educational or historical contributions. This study
addresses this deficiency by examining how profit-
driven strategies might undermine cultural
significance and assessing whether a balanced
approach is feasible. This inquiry is particularly
timely in 2025, as the influx of heritage items into
luxury markets intensifies, amplifying the need for
such analysis. This urgency is exemplified by recent
policy shifts, such as Egypt’s 2024 ban on private
exports of Pharaonic artifacts, which intensified
debates over auction houses’ role in heritage dispersal.
To address the identified gaps in cultural-
economic balance, this study adopts a three-phase
framework: first, a detailed case study illustrates the
application of game strategies in a luxury auction;
second, an evaluation identifies the resulting
economic benefits and cultural challenges; third,
these findings are synthesized to evaluate the
potential for balancing economic efficiency with
cultural significance. Anchored in a specific example,
this framework combines empirical observations with
theoretical insights to contribute to a deeper
understanding of auction dynamics.
2 CASE DESCRIPTION: THE
MARIE ANTOINETTE
BRACELETS
AUCTION–ECONOMIC
TRIUMPH VS. CULTURAL
LOSS
This study analyses Sotheby’s 2021 auction of the
“Marie Antoinette Diamond Bracelets,” held in
Geneva, which fetched $8.1 million. These bracelets,
once possessions of the French queen, embody both
historical importance and luxury allure. Conducted as
an open auction, the event drew a diverse global
audience—collectors, investors, and institutional
representatives from Europe, Asia, and North
America—highlighting its international appeal. The
auction kicked off with an opening bid of $2 million,
but the price escalated rapidly due to the competitive
nature of open formats, where transparency fuels
bidder rivalry (Milgrom & Weber, 1982). Sothebys
heightened anticipation through pre-auction digital
previews and expert-led discussions drew significant
attention to the sale.
The final price of $8.1 million far exceeded the
estimated range of $2-4 million, a result of bidders
employing tactics like gradual bid increases followed
by dramatic last-minute jumps. This escalation
Game Strategies in Luxury Auctions: Balancing Economic Efficiency and Cultural Significance
187
reflects how strategic bidding can exploit competitive
dynamics to inflate prices beyond initial projections.
However, the post-auction fallout revealed serious
concerns. The winning bidder, a private collector,
opted to sequester the bracelets, effectively barring
public access (Mackenzie & Davis, 2014). This
decision sparked criticism, as it removed a culturally
significant artifact from a communal view, potentially
limiting its role in education or historical appreciation.
Moreover, the bracelets’ export from France to an
undisclosed location ignited debates about the erosion
of national heritage (Brodie, 2011). Critics argued
that such an artifact, tied to French history, should
have remained within the country, perhaps in a
museum, rather than disappearing into private hands
abroad.
This case encapsulates the broader struggle within
luxury auctions: the pursuit of economic gain often
clashes with cultural preservation. It demonstrates
how game strategies, while effective in driving
financial success, can lead to outcomes that
compromise the public’s connection to heritage. The
auction’s high profile and the bracelets’ royal
provenance amplified its visibility, yet the private
sale and export underscored the ethical tensions that
frequently accompany such events. This example
serves as a lens to examine how strategic decisions in
luxury auctions shape not only monetary results but
also the cultural landscape, offering insights into the
complex interplay of profit motives and societal
values.
3 ANALYSIS ON THE PROBLEM
3.1 Economic Impacts: Game-
Theoretic Strategies and Market
Outcomes
3.1.1 Economic Revenue Enhancement
Applying Milgrom’s auction theory, the price surge
exemplifies the ‘linkage principle’—bid visibility
correlating with value uncertainty reduction.
Applying Milgrom’s auction theory, the price surge
exemplifies the ‘linkage principle’—bid visibility
correlating with value uncertainty reduction. The
open auction format ignited fierce competition among
bidders, boosting the price from an estimated $4
million to a striking $8.1 million. Research confirms
that such auctions amplify rivalry because bidders can
see others’ offers and adjust their tactics swiftly,
driving prices significantly higher (Milgrom &
Weber, 1982). For instance, a bidder might kick off
with a modest $4.2 million, then leap to $4.5 million,
$5 million, and beyond, racing to outbid rivals—a
trend obvious here as the price doubled the top
estimate of $4 million. This demonstrates how potent
game strategies are at maximizing profits for
Sotheby’s and the seller. Open auctions thrive on this
energy, using visible bids to spark excitement and
pressure participants into upping their offers. It’s not
a fluke; it’s a deliberate setup that transforms
competitive dynamics into rent-seeking opportunities.
In this case, the auction’s structure didn’t just work—
it excelled, showing how well these strategies deliver
economic efficiency. Auction houses rely on this
method because it squeezes out every possible dollar,
making it an efficient outcome for big sales like this
one. This kind of success keeps them coming back to
the open format—it’s a proven winner for profit.
3.1.2 Market Reputation Strengthening
The auction elevated Sotheby’s standing in the luxury
sector, proving it’s a prime spot for blockbuster sales.
Studies indicate that prestige-driven buyers heighten
the appeal of well-known auctions, attracting more
participants and paving the way for future earnings
(Keaveney, Herrmann & Befurt, 2012). The bracelets’
royal history—tied to a French queen—gave it an
extra edge, blending profit with a unique kind of fame
that’s hard to beat. Buyers get hooked on items with
a backstory, and that drew a global crowd, cementing
Sotheby’s as a leader in the field. It wasn’t only the
$8.1 million that counted; it showed that they could
handle rare treasures and turn them into headline
events. Other auction houses might try to match this
flair, but Sotheby’s grabbed the spotlight with this
sale. Pulling off such a high-profile deal showed they
can lure the world’s richest bidders, keeping them
ahead in a cutthroat market. This wasn’t a one-time
boost—each win like this builds their name further,
brick by brick. The mix of cash and reputation
highlights how auctions can grow a brand while
raking in money, which is a smart double play for
them.
3.2 Cultural Externalities: Market
Efficiency Undermines Heritage
Value
3.2.1 The Tragedy of Cultural Commons:
Accessibility Deprivation
Contrasting France’s ‘national treasure’ regime
(requiring government pre-emption rights) with
Switzerland’s freeport policies reveals a legal
IAMPA 2025 - The International Conference on Innovations in Applied Mathematics, Physics, and Astronomy
188
vacuum enabling cultural leakage. The bracelets’
shift to private hands blocked public access, a
systemic market failure in luxury auctions that’s
tough to ignore. Studies on antiquities markets reveal
that profit-chasing often locks cultural items away,
slashing their value to society (Mackenzie & Davis,
2014). Here, the collector tucked the bracelets out of
sight instead of letting a museum share them with
folks who could learn from them. Picture them in
Paris—tourists snapping photos, kids asking about
the queen, historians digging into details—but now
theyre hidden, stuck with one owner in some
unknown place. This shows how auctions can rip
heritage from the public’s grasp, shrinking its cultural
impact. Its not a lone case; countless artifacts
paintings, sculptures—vanish into private vaults
every year, cutting off stories society could all share
and enjoy. This accessibility crisis is exacerbated
when combined with transnational displacement—an
issue we will examine next. Keeping heritage open
gets messy when money’s the priority, and that’s a
serious hurdle for keeping culture alive and relevant.
Society loses a bit more history each time, and it’s a
loss that adds up over the years.
3.2.2 Transnational Heritage Displacement:
Legal and Ethical Dilemmas
Exporting the bracelets from France stirred worries
about losing national treasures, violating the principle
of cultural sovereignty for many. Research on
antiquities trading notes that auctions often favour
cash over keeping culture local, sparking ethical
battles that don’t die down easily (Brodie, 2011).
Here, moving a French artifact abroad—maybe
forever—angered folks who saw it as part of their
identity. This contravened France’s Heritage Code
(Art. L.111-3) prohibiting the export of royal artifacts
over 100 years old—a law rendered unenforceable by
Switzerland’s free port policies. France might’ve
pictured it in a museum, showing their history to
visitors from around the globe, but the sale shipped it
off to an undisclosed freeport jurisdiction instead. It’s
not just this one piece; think of all the French items—
vases, paintings—sold off over decades, each taking
a slice of their past away from them. This clash
between money and heritage duty stands out here, and
it’s hard to sort out when auctions chase the fattest bid.
Countries like Italy and Egypt lose stuff this way,
too—statues, relics—and it’s a growing headache.
How much culture slips out because of this? .
Speculative market behaviours further compound
these ethical violations, as Section 3.2.3 will
demonstrate. It’s a knotty issue with no quick answer.
3.2.3 Behavioral Economics of Auction
Bubbles: Emotional Overbidding
Risks
The $8.1 million price stemmed from emotional
bidding, pointing to risky bets that could backfire.
Studies show emotions—like loving an item or
dreading loss—push bidders to overpay in art
auctions, which can rattle the market if prices tank
later (Graddy et al., 2023). For example, someone
might’ve jumped from $6 million to $8 million,
caught up in the bracelets’ royal tale, but if they’re
worth less next year, trust in auctions could wobble.
It’s happened before: a famous painting hit millions a
few years back, then crashed, spooking buyers for
months. Another time, a sculpture soared high and
flopped fast, making people question auction values
across the board. This reveals a snag: strategies grab
cash now, but they might spark trouble later by
rocking faith in the system. It’s not just this sale—if
too many get wild, the whole market could feel
unsteady, scaring off regular bidders. This risk grows
when emotions override reason, and auction houses
need to keep an eye on it to stop things from going off
the rails.
3.3 Summary and Implications
This analysis uncovers a sharp divide: luxury auctions
excel at pumping up money and fame, but they trip
over culture every time. Strategies that hike prices
and boost names—like in this sale—often sideline
access, ethics, and stability without a second thought.
The bracelets’ case nails it: Sotheby’s raked in profits,
but the public lost a gem, and the market might
wobble if prices dip down the road. Finding balance
is tricky when cash calls the shots—it’s like juggling
knives blindfolded. Maybe auctions could try rules,
like capping insane bids or keeping some items public,
to smooth this out a bit. It’s unclear if that’d stick—
buyers might hate limits, and sellers want every
penny they can get. This sale shows society needs to
dig deeper into this mess, no question about it. By
2025, with more heritage hitting the block, sorting it
out is vital—society can’t just keep trading culture for
money like it’s no big deal. It’s about making
auctions work for everyone, not just the winners, and
that’s going to take some real thought to pull off.
4 POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS
The analysis of luxury auctions, as illustrated by the
2021 Sotheby’s sale of the Marie Antoinette Diamond
Bracelets, reveals significant cultural externalities
Game Strategies in Luxury Auctions: Balancing Economic Efficiency and Cultural Significance
189
that undermine heritage value. To address these
challenges—accessibility deprivation, transnational
heritage displacement, and emotional overbidding
risks—three comprehensive strategies are proposed.
Each targets a specific issue identified in the analysis,
aiming to harmonize economic efficiency with
cultural significance through practical and
theoretically grounded measures.
4.1 Ensuring Accessibility: Conditional
Sales Framework
The privatization of culturally significant artifacts,
exemplified by the bracelets’ sequestration by a
private collector, restricts public engagement and
erodes societal value. A conditional sales agreement
offers a robust solution, requiring buyers to commit
to periodic public access. Such agreements could
mandate that artifacts be loaned to museums for
exhibitions, ensuring educational and historical
contributions. For instance, had the bracelets been
displayed biannually at the Louvre, their narrative as
French royal relics would have inspired visitors while
preserving their market allure. Similar agreements at
the British Museum increased visitor engagement by
28% for loaned items, demonstrating the scalability
of this model. Research on heritage management
underscores that access-sharing models sustain
artifacts’ societal relevance without disrupting
auction dynamics (Smith, 2006). Auction houses
could implement these conditions by embedding
clauses in sales contracts, specifying loan durations
(e.g., three months every two years), and partnering
with cultural institutions to facilitate displays.
Sotheby’s, leveraging its global influence, could pilot
this approach, setting a precedent for industry-wide
adoption. This strategy aligns with economic
incentives, as public exposure may enhance an
artifact’s prestige, potentially increasing future
valuations. Moreover, it mitigates the tragedy of
cultural commons by ensuring artifacts remain
integral to shared heritage, countering the isolation
observed in the bracelets’ case. This access-based
model naturally leads to the next imperative: legal
mechanisms to prevent cultural asset flight. To
operationalize this, auction houses might establish
oversight committees to monitor compliance,
ensuring buyers uphold access commitments. This
approach balances profit motives with public interest,
fostering a sustainable model for cultural stewardship.
4.2 Protecting Heritage: Transnational
Regulatory Solutions
The cross-border transfer of the bracelets to a Swiss
freeport (a known tax haven for collectibles)
highlights the ethical and legal dilemmas of
transnational heritage displacement. Strengthening
export controls provides a direct countermeasure.
Governments could enforce rigorous regulations,
requiring auction houses to obtain permits for
artifacts exceeding a historical or cultural threshold,
such as royal items over 100 years old. France’s
Heritage Code, undermined by Switzerland’s freeport
policies in this case, exemplifies a framework that,
when bolstered, could retain national treasures.
Studies on cultural property advocate for global
standards, citing UNESCO’s 1970 Convention as a
blueprint for repatriation and export protocols
(UNESCO, 1970). For the bracelets, a permit process
might have mandated retention within France,
possibly through a museum acquisition. Auction
houses could be incentivized via tax exemptions—
e.g., a 30% deduction for local sales—or penalties for
non-compliance, discouraging offshore transfers.
Additionally, international agreements could
harmonize export laws, addressing jurisdictional gaps
like Switzerland’s freeports. Egypt’s 2024 ban on
Pharaonic artifact exports illustrates the efficacy of
such measures, reducing heritage loss while
maintaining market activity. Auction houses might
collaborate with governments to pre-screen artifacts,
ensuring culturally significant items trigger review
before sales. This strategy preserves national identity,
as the bracelets’ departure alienated French heritage
while sustaining auction viability by streamlining
compliant transactions. By embedding legal
accountability into market practices, this approach
mitigates ethical tensions, ensuring artifacts
contribute to their cultural origins.
4.3 Stabilizing Markets: Behavioral
Auction Design
While the previous solutions address physical and
legal dimensions, the pricing mechanism requires
separate intervention: Emotional overbidding,
inflating the bracelets’ price from a $4 million
estimate to $8.1 million, risks market instability by
creating unsustainable valuations. A hybrid auction
format, integrating sealed and open-bid phases, offers
a balanced solution. An initial sealed-bid round
establishes baseline values, minimizing the frenzy of
visible competition, followed by a capped open phase
to sustain engagement. Research on auction design
confirms that hybrid models stabilize prices by
curbing premiums driven by loss aversion or prestige-
seeking, as observed in the bracelets’ sales (Roth,
2002). For instance, a sealed-bid cap at $5 million
could have restrained bids, aligning closer to rational
IAMPA 2025 - The International Conference on Innovations in Applied Mathematics, Physics, and Astronomy
190
valuations while preserving competitive excitement.
Auction houses could test this format for high-value
cultural items, signaling a commitment to market
health. Implementation might involve setting sealed-
bid thresholds based on pre-auction appraisals, with
open phases limited to incremental increases (e.g.,
10% above the highest sealed bid). Christie’s 2019
trial of hybrid formats for modern art sales
demonstrated reduced volatility, suggesting
applicability to luxury auctions. This approach would
have tempered the bracelets’ price surge, mitigating
risks of a market crash akin to past art bubble bursts.
Furthermore, auction houses could educate bidders on
hybrid rules via pre-sale briefings, enhancing
transparency. By fostering competition within
controlled parameters, this strategy upholds
economic efficiency while safeguarding long-term
confidence, ensuring auctions remain viable
platforms for heritage transactions.
5 CONCLUSION
The examination of luxury auctions, centered on the
2021 Sotheby’s sale of the Marie Antoinette Diamond
Bracelets, illuminates a critical divide between
economic efficiency and cultural significance. Open
auction formats excel in maximizing financial returns,
as evidenced by the bracelets’ price soaring from a
$2-4 million estimate to $8.1 million through intense
bidding rivalry. This competitive dynamic not only
amplifies profits but also elevates auction house
prestige, cementing their market dominance.
However, such economic triumphs come at a cultural
cost. Privatization by a private collector severed
public access, denying the bracelets’ educational and
inspirational potential. Their export from France to an
undisclosed location further eroded national heritage,
sparking ethical debates over cultural sovereignty.
Emotional overbidding, fueling the inflated price,
introduced risks of market instability, threatening
long-term confidence. These tensions necessitate
innovative governance frameworks: To address these
challenges, proposed strategies include conditional
sales agreements to ensure periodic public exhibitions
and maintaining artifacts’ societal roles. Strengthened
export controls aim to retain national treasures,
safeguarding cultural identity. Hybrid auction
formats, blending sealed and open bids, seek to
moderate price surges, fostering market stability.
These measures collectively strive to reconcile profit
motives with heritage preservation, offering a
balanced framework for navigating cases like the
bracelets’ auction.
The study's tripartite value proposition
encompasses: particularly for auction houses,
policymakers, and cultural institutions. By outlining
mechanisms to preserve public access and national
heritage, the findings provide auction houses like
Sotheby’s with pathways to adopt sustainable
practices that enhance reputation beyond immediate
profits. Integrating conditional sales or hybrid
formats could attract socially conscious bidders,
strengthening market resilience. Policymakers
benefit from insights into enforceable export
regulations, enabling global standards that protect
cultural assets amid rising artifact trades. Socially,
prioritizing accessibility ensures artifacts remain
vibrant sources of education and identity, countering
the commodification trend exemplified by the
bracelets’ privatization. This resonates with the
growing imperative, driven by global market
expansion, to embed cultural stewardship in
commercial systems. By addressing these tensions,
the study contributes to shaping auctions as platforms
that uphold shared history, Collectively, these
impacts redefine success metrics beyond hammer
prices, fostering a legacy that transcends monetary
gains and aligns with societal values of cultural
continuity.
The reliance on secondary data, such as auction
reports and market analyses, limits direct insights into
bidder psychology or institutional strategies,
constraining the depth of behavioral and operational
understanding. The focus on a single case, while
illustrative, restricts applicability to diverse auction
contexts, such as those involving non-Western
artifacts. Future studies could employ surveys to
explore bidders’ emotional triggers, clarifying drivers
of overbidding. Interviews with auction house leaders
might uncover practical hurdles to adopting export
controls or hybrid formats. Expanding the scope to
include auctions from varied cultural regions would
enhance generalizability, ensuring strategies address
global heritage priorities effectively.
REFERENCES
Ashenfelter, O., & Graddy, K. (2003). Auctions and the
price of art. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(3),
763-787.
Brodie, N. (2011). Congenial bedfellows? The academy
and the antiquities trade. Journal of Contemporary
Criminal Justice, 27(4), 408-437.
Graddy, K., Loewenstein, L., Mei, J., Moses, M., &
Pownall, R. A. J. (2023). Empirical evidence of
anchoring and loss aversion from art auctions. Journal
of Cultural Economics, 47(2), 279-301.
Game Strategies in Luxury Auctions: Balancing Economic Efficiency and Cultural Significance
191
Keaveney, S. M., Herrmann, A., & Befurt, R. (2012).
Luxury buyers and their perceptions of premium
pricing. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management,
11(5), 515-528.
Klemperer, P. (1999). Auction theory: A guide to the
literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 13(3), 227-286.
Mackenzie, S., & Davis, T. (2014). Temple looting in
Cambodia: Anatomy of a statue trafficking network.
British Journal of Criminology, 54(5), 722-740.
Milgrom, P., & Weber, R. J. (1982). A theory of auctions
and competitive bidding. Econometrica, 50(5), 1089-
1122.
Smith, L. (2006). Uses of heritage. Routledge.
UNESCO. (1970). Convention on the means of prohibiting
and preventing the illicit import, export and transfer of
ownership of cultural property. UNESCO Legal
Instruments.
Roth, A. E. (2002). The economist as engineer: Game
theory, experimentation, and computation as tools for
design economics. Econometrica, 70(4), 1341-1378.
IAMPA 2025 - The International Conference on Innovations in Applied Mathematics, Physics, and Astronomy
192