Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model:
Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
Yi Cao
1a
and Xueru Wen
2,3,* b
1
China Institute of Geo-Environment Monitoring, Beijing 100081, China
2
Institute of Hydrogeology and Environmental Geology, CAGS, Hebei 050061, China
3
Field Research Base for Groundwater Sciences and Engineering, Ministry of Natural Resources, Hebei 050061, China
*
Keywords: Watershed Ecological Environment Protection; Game Theory; Environmental Incentive Model.
Abstract: The coordinated development of river basins requires prioritizing ecological considerations despite
persistent institutional challenges. To engage stakeholders in ecological and environmental protection, it is
crucial to define the responsibilities and authority dynamics between the central government, local
government, and enterprises. Incentive-compatible mechanisms must be established across administrative
units to harmonize environmental protection efforts, promote unified approaches, and contribute to
sustainable basin development.
The central-local government relationship resembles a principal-agent dynamic. To achieve optimal risk
allocation, the central government must exert influence on the local government, enforce contractual
obligations, and establish incentivized frameworks. "Free riding" behavior by local governments in
ecological protection arises from vested interests. By employing rational game theory, it becomes apparent
that an integrated supervisory mechanism allows the central government to maximize basin environmental
utility. Aligning standards among the three government levels and increasing the costs of illicit activities by
enterprises are essential measures to deter collusion.Based on these analyses, several key policy
recommendations emerge. Firstly, elevate the importance of environmental protection performance in the
assessment and evaluation of all government levels. Secondly, establish a comprehensive environmental
protection coordination organization at the basin level. Thirdly, optimize industrial structure adjustment
policies while considering resource and environmental constraints. Fourthly, gradually implement a regional
emission trading market within the environmental regulation framework. Lastly, enhance grassroots
government enforcement capacities regarding environmental protection laws.
Implementing these policies facilitates the coordinated development of river basins, providing a robust
framework for ecological and environmental protection. It ensures sustainable and harmonious basin
development while mitigating the adverse impacts of human activities.
a
https://orcid.org/0009-0006-2096-4941
b
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8633-6204
1 INTRODUCTION
In order to enhance the ecological and
environmental quality of river basins, governments
at various levels have acknowledged the inherent
trade-off between economic growth and
environmental protection. The challenge lies in
addressing the conflicting interests between survival
and development while simultaneously fostering
cooperation, strengthening complementarity, and
unifying responsibilities and rights. Extensive
research (Fu Y, 2021; Zhang ZM, 2022; Zu J, 2021;
Zu J, 2021; Kong SJ, 2021; Li LQ, 2021; Zhang JH,
2022; Wu SM, 2022; Zhang X, 2021) has identified
several key factors contributing to the deterioration
of watershed environments, which can be
categorized as follows:
Firstly, industrial economic growth often results
in environmental pollution, with governmental
performance evaluations primarily focused on GDP
118
Cao, Y., Wen and X.
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion.
DOI: 10.5220/0013574400004671
In Proceedings of the 7th International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering (ICESCE 2024), pages 118-129
ISBN: 978-989-758-764-1; ISSN: 3051-701X
Copyright © 2025 by Paper published under CC license (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0)
metrics.Secondly, the ecological environment is
considered a public good, and the prevalence of
free-riding mentalities leads to inadequate
investment and efforts in comprehensive
environmental protection. Disparities in capital
investment, environmental protection capabilities,
and pollution control levels among local
governments hinder collaborative efforts and joint
initiatives.
Thirdly, the implementation of environmental
protection measures is impeded by the interplay of
interests between governments and enterprises,
hierarchical conflicts between higher and lower
levels of government, and the presence of
rent-seeking collusion and fraudulent practices
within market conditions. Each entity pursues the
maximization of its own interests, which can result
in buck-passing, inefficiency, or even inaction.
Effective mechanism design plays a pivotal role
in achieving overall utility maximization, thereby
facilitating continuous improvement of the basin's
ecological environment. Thus, drawing upon game
theory as a theoretical framework, this study
introduces three levels of environmental protection
incentive models. The application of game theory in
the realm of environmental resource protection
focuses on examining the relationship between
upstream and downstream water usage and the
development of ecological compensation
mechanisms to achieve a balance of interests.
Additionally, it encompasses game analyses of
environmental regulation strategies among local
governments, hierarchical administrative systems,
behavioral choices between the central government
and local governments guided by GDP performance,
and the decision-making processes involving
governmental entities and polluting enterprises (Luo
Y, 2021; Li X, 2021; Hu HJ, 2017; Hong WH, 2021;
Han ST, 2021; Du YT, 2021; Zhou W, 2021; Lu S,
2021; Zhang GH, 2022; Yang L, 2021; Qin JH, 2021;
Ye SS, 2019).
2 CENTRAL GOVERNMENT AND
LOCAL GOVERNMENT
ENVIRONMENTAL
PROTECTION INCENTIVE
MODEL
The central government assumes the responsibility
of formulating pertinent high-level strategies, while
local governments serve as the specific executors of
various policies, regulations, and agreements.
Nevertheless, the presence of "policies at the top and
countermeasures at the bottom," compounded by the
inherent uncertainty associated with ecological and
environmental assessments, renders the central
government the "uninformed party" acting as the
principal, while the local government assumes the
role of the "informed party" as the agent.
Consequently, the principal-agent model proves
valuable in analyzing the strategic interaction
between the central government and local
government in the context of protecting the
watershed's ecological environment.
Premise 1: The central government, acting as the
trustee, does not directly contribute to the
enhancement of the basin's ecological environment.
Instead, the responsibility for ecological
environment protection and improvement lies with
the local government, which perceives the central
government as being risk-neutral while considering
itself as risk-averse.
Premise 2: Due to the lack of direct observation
of the environmental protection actions and their
outcomes by local governments, the central
government faces a dearth of timely, accurate, and
sufficient feedback information.
Let us denote A as the set of possible actions
available to local governments for ecological
environmental protection, where "a" represents a
specific action and "aA". The exogenous random
variable θ, representing the state of the natural
ecological environment, is beyond the control of
both the central government and the local
government. Suppose the local government
implements action "a", then the joint influence of
"a" and the exogenous variable θ determines a
quantifiable income denoted as π(a,θ), which serves
as a measure of the outcomes achieved. The function
π is monotonically increasing with respect to both
"a" and θ. In other words, higher values of θ indicate
more favorable natural conditions, while larger
values of "a" represent more favorable ecological
and environmental protection behaviors by the local
government, resulting in greater quantifiable
benefits for the central government.
Given the inability of the central government to
directly observe or measure "a" and θ, the focus is
on designing an incentive contract denoted as "s(π)"
that rewards and penalizes local governments (not
solely in a physical sense) based on observed
outcomes. This incentivizes local governments to
take actions that maximize the expected utility
function of the central government.
Furthermore, the V-N-M (von
Neumann-Morgenstern) expected utility functions of
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
119
the central government and the local government are
defined as "v[π - s(π)]" and "u[s(π)]", respectively,
where "v' > 0" and "v'' 0" denote the first and
second derivatives of "v", and "u' > 0" and "u'' 0"
denote the first and second derivatives of "u". To
provide a more intuitive interpretation of the
mathematical model, let us consider two possible
values for "a": "P" representing "environmental
protection" and "D" representing "environmental
destruction".
() ( )
() () ( ) ()
() () () () () () ()
- ,
.. , -
,- ,-
MAX v p s p f P p a dp
st IR usp fPpadp cP
ū
IC u s p fP p a dp c P u s p fD p a dp c D




 

(1)
Let "f(π,a)" represent the density function
associated with the derived distribution function.
The variable "c" signifies the cost of the action,
while "(I)" denotes the desired utility obtained when
the incentive contract "s(π)" cannot be accepted.
Formula (IR) represents the participation constraint,
and Formula (IC) represents the incentive
compatibility constraint.
Let "λ" and "μ" represent the Lagrange
multipliers associated with the participation
constraint (IR) and the incentive compatibility
constraint (IC), respectively. The first-order
condition of the aforementioned optimization
problem is as follows:
() () () ()
,,,-,0vfPpa lufPpa mufP p a mufD p a′+′+ =
To sort out:
() () ( ) ( )
-/ 1-,/,vpsp usp l m fDpa fPpa


′=+

(2)
To achieve the objectives of ecological and
environmental protection, the central government
must impose constraints on local governments in at
least two dimensions. Firstly, there is the
participation constraint, which ensures that the
expected utility gained by local governments from
accepting the incentive contract is not lower than the
maximum expected utility attained without
accepting the contract. The second dimension
involves the conflicting choices that local
governments face, often referred to as the
opportunity cost of environmental protection. It
pertains to the trade-off between pursuing their own
interests and engaging in environmental protection
efforts.
Furthermore, the incentives provided to local
governments must align with the constraints they
face. Given that the central government lacks the
ability to directly observe the specific behaviors and
natural conditions of local governments, local
governments will always strive to maximize their
expected utility under any given incentive contract.
Unless the central government offers adequate
incentives to local governments regarding
environmental protection policies, it is unlikely that
the efforts and actions of local governments in
related endeavors will meet the desired expectations.
In Scenario 1, when the behaviors of local
governments are observable, the central government
can enforce the required actions through compulsory
contracts. This entails the diligent implementation of
collaborative work plans for ecological and
environmental protection in the basin, as issued by
the central government. Corresponding payments are
provided by the central government to ensure that
the local government is either "profitable" or
exposed to the lowest possible risk.
In this context, when the central government can
monitor the actions of local governments and the
associated risks are minimal, a system is established
where local governments achieve the minimum
environmental targets (guaranteed income), while
the central government assumes the full risk for
subpar environmental protection (residual income).
Through the enforcement of compulsory contracts,
the central government can effectively compel local
governments to align their actions with the
requirements set forth by the central government.
So if I set
μ
equal to 0, I get
() ()
-/us us
ππ π
λ


′=
(3)
In Scenario 2, when the behaviors of local
governments are unobservable, information
asymmetry arises between the central government
and the local government, resulting in the
coexistence of risks and incentives. The optimal
risk-sharing contract is determined based on the
observed outcomes, whereby greater efforts by the
local government lead to higher outputs. When the
ICESCE 2024 - The International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering
120
local government assumes all the risks, the contract
incentives are sufficient, enabling the central
government to maximize its expected outcomes.
However, when local governments bear some of the
risks, their level of effort will depend on the
incentives provided by the central government.
In reality, μ=0 does not exist because of the
asymmetrical information between the principal
(central government) and the agent (local
government), indicating that μ>0. We represent the
risk-sharing contract under μ=0 and μ>0 as s(π) and
sλ(π), respectively. If the density function fP(π,a) is
greater than or equal to fD(π,a), the contract s(π) is
greater than or equal to sλ(π). Conversely, if fP(π,a)
is less than or equal to fD(π,a), then s(π) is less than
or equal to sλ(π). For a given output, if the
probability fD(π,a) of the agent "damaging the
environment" is greater than the probability fP(π,a)
of "protecting the environment," the agent's expected
returns will be adjusted downward, and vice versa.
In summary, to achieve Pareto optimal risk
sharing, the central government needs to effectively
"compel" local governments to implement
"contracts" that involve the decomposition of
environmental protection tasks into multiple layers.
This requires the central government to have
comprehensive and accurate evaluations of the
ecological and environmental protection behaviors
of local governments through relevant indicators or
actual observations. However, within the current
governance system, task decomposition is primarily
carried out by local governments, rendering the
existence of compulsory contracts no longer feasible.
Furthermore, the central government still faces
considerable uncertainties in assessing watershed
ecological environmental protection. Consequently,
the present approach is limited to implementing
overall constraints on major environmental
indicators. Until the two levels of government
achieve the Pareto optimal risk-sharing ratio, there
remains significant room for strategic interaction
and negotiation.
3 GAME ANALYSIS BETWEEN
UPPER AND LOWER RIVER
BASIN LOCAL
GOVERNMENTS
3.1 General Forms of Games Among
Local Governments
The concept of a watershed is applicable to both
water resources and atmospheric environments. In
this context, it is assumed that both the upstream and
downstream governments have a comprehensive
understanding of each other's strategic space and
benefit functions. Consequently, the game of
ecological compensation between the upstream and
downstream governments in the basin can be
characterized as a static non-cooperative game with
complete information. By considering the income
functions of both parties, a cost-benefit matrix can
be established. The upstream government has two
strategic choices: protection and non-protection,
while the downstream government has two strategic
choices: compensation and non-compensation.
The original income of the upstream government
is denoted as "b," and it incurs a direct cost "c" for
implementing protection measures, as well as an
opportunity cost associated with potential losses.
Environmental improvement also yields benefits for
the upstream government. The original revenue of
the downstream government is represented by "b
0
,"
and it incurs a cost "c
0
" for providing compensation
to the upstream government. Additionally, the
upstream environmental protection efforts result in
external revenue denoted as "b
1
" through
environmental improvement. When the upstream
government selects the "no protection" strategy and
the downstream government chooses the
"compensation" strategy, the corresponding payoff is
(b+c, b
0
+c). On the other hand, if the upstream
government selects the "no protection" strategy and
the downstream government chooses the "no
compensation" strategy, the payoff becomes (b
0
, b).
When the upstream government chooses the
"protection" strategy and the downstream
government selects the "compensation" strategy, the
respective benefits are (b
0
-c
0
+b
1
, b+b
i
-c+c
0
).For
upstream governments, if the benefit "b
i
" outweighs
the cost "c," they will undoubtedly opt for protection
strategies, regardless of whether downstream
governments provide compensation or not. In
practice, the income lost by the upstream
government due to environmental protection
measures far exceeds the compensation provided by
the downstream government, that is, b
i
<c. Therefore,
in the absence of external constraints, the upstream
government, driven by rational decision-making,
tends to pursue a non-protection strategy to
maximize short-term self-interest gains.
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
121
Table 1: Game models of upstream and downstream governments
Upstream government
Protection Not protect
Downstream
government
Com
p
ensation
(
b
0
-c
0
+b
1
,b+b
i
-c+c
0
)
(
b
0
-c
0
,b+c
0
)
Non-com
p
ensation
(
b
0
+b
1
,b+b
i
-c
)
(
b
0
,b
)
The downstream government finds it
advantageous not to provide compensation when
the upstream government implements protection
strategies. Similarly, even if the upstream
government does not engage in protection
measures, the downstream government will still
choose not to provide
compensation. Consequently,
unless the externality income (b
1
) resulting from
upstream environmental improvement is greater
than zero, downstream governments tend to
free-ride and lack sufficient motivation for
ecological compensation. Although the
establishment of an ecological compensation
mechanism can effectively alleviate the conflict
between ecological environmental protection and
economic and social development in the water
source areas of river basins, practical
implementation is hindered by ambiguous
collaborative positioning at the district and county
levels, as well as institutional and procedural
obstacles. Additionally, technical challenges arise
in measuring the value of ecological services and
determining the scope of compensation, which
restricts the extent of ecological compensation
from downstream to upstream. Currently,
negotiations are primarily limited to specific
"points and lines" within a certain timeframe, and
progress on a broader scale has been sluggish.
3.2 Game between Players and Local
Governments
The interactions among local governments in the
basin can be compared to a "smart pig game" given
the presence of multiple administrative levels as well
as significant variations in social and economic scale
and structure. Let us denote A as a subset of local
governments in the basin characterized by a
developed economy and abundant environmental
protection funds, while B represents a larger set of
local governments in the basin with an
underdeveloped economy and limited investment in
environmental protection funds.
We assume that the overall ecological
environment level of the basin is denoted as X, and
the level of improvement in the ecological
environment resulting from human action is X+R.
Furthermore, X+P represents the input cost of
environmental protection required to achieve the
corresponding level. For any local government in the
basin, without any efforts, its expected income is
E(X+λ
1R
), where λ
1
represents the probability that
the local government does not engage in
environmental protection measures but still benefits
from the improvement in the ecological environment.
On the other hand, the probability that the local
government actively participates in environmental
protection and contributes to the improvement of the
ecological environment is denoted as λ
2
, with the
associated cost level being E(X+λ
2P
). In general, we
expect that λ
2
≥λ
1
, indicating that local government
investment in environmental protection is conducive
to the overall improvement of the basin's ecological
environment.
For local government A, it will choose to
actively strengthen environmental protection and
participate in watershed environmental governance
to improve the overall ecological environment level
as long as it satisfies the condition λ
2P
λ
1r
, or
equivalently, P≥ λ
1r
/λ
2
, and P<R. However, for local
government B, its investment in environmental
protection funds is limited and has little impact on
the probability of improving the overall level of the
basin's ecological environment. In this case, we can
simplify the situation by assuming that λ
2
1
. To
motivate local government B to engage in
environmental protection, it must meet the condition
P≥R. As a result, the cost of environmental
protection exceeds the benefits, and local
government B chooses not to pursue optimal
environmental protection strategies.
The reason why local government B tends to act
as a "free rider" is that it perceives "more gains than
losses" in actively engaging in environmental
protection. It expects other local governments to
increase their investment in environmental
protection and improve the ecological environment
of the basin, from which it can benefit without
incurring the associated cost. On the other hand, the
intensity of environmental protection investment by
local government A determines whether the
ecological environment of the basin can be improved.
As a result, local government A bears the cost of
increasing environmental protection investment,
ICESCE 2024 - The International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering
122
which benefits not only itself but laso other local
governments, including B. If local government A
chooses not to act or adopts the same behavior as
local government B, all local governments in the
basin may refrain from increasing their
environmental protection efforts, making it
challenging to achieve the goal of improving the
ecological environment.
There are two potential solutions to address this
issue. First, implementing the principle of "those
who engage in environmental protection will
benefit" More strictly. This approach can help to
partially curb the issue of unearned gains, but it
requires linking environmental protection to
performance rewards and penalties, ensuring a better
balance between costs and benefits. The second
solution involves clarifying the responsibilities and
tasks of each actor and holding them accountable for
their lack of action in accordance with assessment
requirements, reward systems, and penalties.
Ultimately, the core of the local government game
lies in defining and allocating property rights,
including ownership, use, income, and disposal
rights of ecological environmental resources.
Breakthroughs in the basin's fiscal and tax system,
assessment mechanisms, and existing interest
patterns are needed to address this challenge
effectively (Yuan RX, 2021; Guo H, 2020; Wang CG,
2022; Kim Y, 2022; Yu Y, 2022; Yang C, 2021; Shi
SH, 2022; Zhang PP, 2020; Xie FF, 2021; Yang HF,
2022; Wang N, 2021; Yu HS, 2021; Zhao YW, 2020).
Let us consider the scenario without any external
constraints. In this context, we define Uc as the
ecological and environmental benefits accruing to
downstream governments, mc as the level of
implementation of environmental protection
measures, p as the level of environmental damage,
g(mc) as the cost associated with protection efforts,
and T(p) as the expenditure required for ecological
compensation. On the other hand, Ud represents the
environmental benefits received by the upstream
government, H(md) denotes the revenue function of
the upstream government, and md represents the
level of implementation of environmental protection
measures. When the upstream government
successfully implements protective measures, it
becomes eligible for compensation from the
downstream government. It is important to note that
environmental damage primarily impacts the
downstream region. Additionally, j(md) represents
the additional cost incurred by ecological
compensation for environmental protection, while
T(p) signifies the ecological compensation received.
max ( ; ) - ( ) - ( )Uc F mcp gmcTp=
(4)
max ( ) ( ) - ( )Ud H mdTpjmd=+
(5)
It is evident that when the sum of ecological
compensation (T(p)) and protection costs (g(mc)) is
relatively low, the environmental benefits received
by downstream governments primarily rely on the
extent of environmental damage caused by upstream
governments. On the other hand, the ecological
benefits received by downstream governments are
determined by the difference between ecological
compensation (T(p)) and the additional protection
costs (j(md)). It is observed that the ecological
compensation provided by upstream governments is
insufficient to cover the extra costs incurred for
protection, rendering the situation "worth the cost."
This highlights the presence of conflicting interests
between the two parties. As the negative impact of
upstream non-protection escalates and downstream
motivation for ecological compensation increases, it
becomes rational for upstream governments to
disengage until both parties return to the negotiation
table. However, the irreversible or costly nature of
ecological degradation exacerbates the
aforementioned contradictions.
To address these challenges, the central
government can be reintegrated as the
decision-maker within the integration mechanism. In
this framework, "a" represents the interest subject
representing policy makers, while "b" represents
local governments responsible for policy
implementation. Ua and Ub denote the revenue
generated by the central government and local
government, respectively. The revenue function of
the central government is denoted as I(ma; p), where
ma signifies the central government's oversight of
local governments, and p represents the degree of
environmental resource damage and waste.
Furthermore, ma is a function of p, represented as
ma(p). The maximum utility function of the central
government can be expressed as maxUa=I(ma;
p)-i(ma)-L(p), where i(ma)+L(p) represents the total
costs incurred by the central government.
Specifically, i(ma) denotes the costs associated with
central government supervision over local
governments, which increase with the magnitude of
ma. Meanwhile, L(p) indicates that environmental
damage prevents the central government from
achieving resource protection targets.
Similarly, the maximum utility function of local
governments can be expressed as maxUb=E;
ma)-e(ma)-S(mb). Here, E(mb; ma) represents the
revenue function of local governments, where mb
signifies the level of environmental protection
intensity, and mb is a function of ma denoted as
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
123
mb(ma). Increased supervision or penalties from the
central government prompt local governments to
invest more in ecological and environmental
protection. The total costs incurred by local
governments are represented by e(ma)+S(mb),
where e(ma) refers to the additional protection costs
due to central government oversight, and S(mb)
represents the costs borne by local governments for
environmental protection. The equilibrium
relationship that maximizes utility for both parties
can be expressed using the following formula.
max ( ; ) ( ) ( )Ua I map i maLp=−
(6)
max ( ; ) ( ) ( )Ub E mbmaemaSmb=−
(7)
() 0
() 0
IIi
mamaLp
mapma
EEe
mbmaSmb
mbmama
∂∂
′′
+− =
∂∂
∂∂
′′
+− =
∂∂
(8)
The solution to this problem lies in identifying a
set of optimal values that simultaneously establish
ma
*
=ma(p
*
) and mb
*
=mb(ma
*
). This entails
achieving a delicate equilibrium among the degree
of ecological and environmental damage, the level
of central government supervision, and the extent of
protection input by local governments. By attaining
this balance, all parties involved can concurrently
maximize their utility..
4 GAME ANALYSIS BETWEEN
LOCAL GOVERNMENT AND
ENTERPRISE
In the context of ecological environmental
protection, local governments play a crucial role in
supervision and management, while enterprises
serve as the ultimate subjects of behavior (Liu M,
2021; LI WY, 2019; Zhou NQ, 2019; Zhang Y, 2022;
Li B, 2021; Dang XY, 2021; Dang YX, 2022; Cheng
CS, 2021). However, during the process of law
enforcement, regulatory bodies at various levels
within the river basin possess significant
discretionary power. This discretion often leads to a
lack of uniform objective standards and subjective
inaction. For instance, the phenomenon of "APEC
Blue" resulted from the stringent joint prevention
and control efforts undertaken by three local
governments. In many cases, information asymmetry
exists between the government, regulators, and
enterprises, making it challenging for the
government to effectively control the enforcement
efforts of regulators. This information asymmetry
can also give rise to collusive activities between
regulators and enterprises to gain illegal profits, as
well as instances of regulatory oversight and
ineffective investigation of environmental pollution
incidents (Yu SK, 2022; Niu Y, 2021; Shima Nasiri,
2022; Liu QS, 2021; Xu J, 2021; Wei P, 2022; Deng
XB, 2021; Wei C, 2021; Yuan SH, 2021).
4.1 Model Establishment and
Hypotheses
Firstly, it is assumed that there is no collusion
between regulators and enterprises to fabricate data.
In this scenario, if the local government does not
conduct any inspections, the additional income
obtained by regulators and enterprises is zero, while
the government's income (representing the degree of
environmental protection goal attainment) is denoted
as R. The income of the government, regulators, and
enterprises is recorded as: (R, 0, 0).
Secondly, assuming no collusion between
regulators and enterprises, but the government still
carries out inspections, resulting in increased costs
denoted as S, the income of the government,
regulators, and enterprises is recorded as: (R - S, 0,
0).
Thirdly, if the regulator and the enterprise
conspire to fabricate data, and the government does
not conduct any inspections, the respective earnings
of the regulator and the enterprise are denoted as U
and V. In this case, the income of the government,
regulator, and enterprise is recorded as: (0, U, V).
Fourthly, if the regulator and the enterprise
collude to fabricate data, even though the
government conducts inspections, it fails to identify
the issue. Then, the income of the government,
regulator, and enterprise is denoted as (-S, U, V).
Fifthly, if the regulator and the enterprise collude
to fabricate data, the government conducts
inspections, and the collusion is discovered and
punished. Then, the income of the government,
regulator, and enterprise is denoted as (-S + G, -O,
-T), where G represents the income from
government fines, -O represents the punishment
imposed on the regulator, and -T represents the
losses incurred by the enterprise as a result of
investigation and punishment.
Lastly, let P
1
represent the probability of
collusion between regulators and enterprises, P
2
represent the probability of government inspections,
and P
3
represent the probability of government
ICESCE 2024 - The International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering
124
inspections uncovering collusion. The tripartite
game model is presented in Table 2.
Table 2: Three-party game model
supervisor
Check (P
2
) Do not check (1-P
2
)
Verify (P
3
)
Failure to verify
(
1-P
3
)
Conspiracy to
commit fraud
(P
1
)
(R-S+G,-O,-T) (-S,U,V) (0,U,V)
No conspiracy
to defraud
(1-P
1
)
(R-S,0,0) (R-S,0,0) (R,0,0)
4.2 Model solving
Let us consider the scenario where the probability of
collusion between regulators and enterprises is
denoted as P
1
. In this case, the government's income
is determined by two situations: when conducting
inspections and when not conducting inspections,
which are represented as
π
1
and
π
2
, respectively.
( ) ()()()()()
()
11 3 3 1 3 3
21
11 1
1
PRSGP S P P RSP RS P
PR
π
π


=−++ +
=
(9)
When the expected benefits of government
verification and non-verification are the same, it is
the optimal probability of collusion between
regulators and enterprises when the government is in
game equilibrium.Setting
π
1
=
π
2
, we obtain the
following.
*
/
133
PSRPPG=+
(10)
Suppose that the probability of the government's
verification is P
2
, then the enterprise's income from
collusion is
π
3
and that from no collusion is
π
4
,
respectively:
()
(
)
(
)
11
323 3 2
0
4
PP T PV PV
π
π

= +− +−


=
(11)
When the expected returns of enterprises'
collusion and non-collusion are the same, it is the
optimal probability of the government's verification
when enterprises are in game equilibrium. Let
π
3
=
π
4
, we get:
()
*
/
23
PV TVP=+
(12)
Suppose that the probability of the government's
inspection is P
2
, then the benefits of collusion by
supervisors are
π
5
and
π
6
, respectively:
() ( ) ( )
523 3 2
6
11
0
PP O U P U P
π
π

=−++
=

(13)
When the expected benefits of collusion and
non-collusion of regulators are the same, that is,
when the regulators are in game equilibrium, the
optimal probability of the government's verification.
Let π
5
= π
6
,, we get:
()
*
/
23
PUUOP=+
(14)
According to equations (10), (12) and (14), Nash
equilibrium of the tripartite game model of
government, regulators and enterprises can be
obtained as follows:
()
*
133
*
23
/ *
/
PSRPPO
PVTVP
=+
=+
(15)
Or
()
*
133
*
23
/ *
/
PSRPPO
PUUOP
=+
=+
(16)
The formula presented earlier demonstrates that
the probability P1 of collusion between regulators
and enterprises is directly proportional to the cost S
incurred by the government during inspections.
Conversely, the probability P
3
of collusion being
detected during inspections is inversely proportional
to the government's income R and the penalty
income O. This implies that higher enforcement
capabilities and technical proficiency of the
government in environmental protection verification
lead to a lower likelihood of collusion between
regulators and enterprises. However, if the cost of
government inspections becomes excessively high,
the frequency of inspections may be reduced to
mitigate expenses, consequently resulting in a
corresponding decrease in the probability of
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
125
collusion between regulators and enterprises.
Ultimately, this may lead to a decline in the
government's anticipated benefits from
environmental protection.
According to the formula, when P
2
is lower than
the Nash equilibrium probability P
2
*
(i.e., V/(T+V)P
3
or U/(U+O)P
3
), the government's inspection
probability is below the equilibrium level, prompting
enterprises to choose collusion. Conversely, if P
2
is
greater than the smaller P
2
*
value, enterprises opt not
to collude. Assuming a constant value for V, an
increase in the loss T incurred due to collusion
results in a higher verification probability P
3
during
inspections, causing V/(T+V)P
3
to decrease and
consequently reducing P
2
*
. Similarly, if the loss O
resulting from collusion becomes larger, the
likelihood of collusion decreases. Only when the
government's verification probability P
2
falls below
the smaller P
2
*
value, enterprises are more likely to
collude.
Assuming a significant increase in V, leading to a
corresponding increase in P
2
*
, it is essential for the
government to simultaneously raise the actual
verification probability P
2
. Failing to do so may
encourage regulators and enterprises to engage in
fraudulent activities. If V reaches a sufficiently high
level and T becomes negligible in comparison,
enterprises may continue to engage in pollution even
if the probability of investigation and verification
(P
3
) is 1. Therefore, reducing collusion hinges on the
government increasing the penalties for collusion,
while also augmenting the losses incurred by
enterprises during investigations and punishments
(i.e., raising the costs of illegal environmental
pollution) serves as a potent strategy to deter
excessive pollution by enterprises.
5 CONCLUSIONS
5.1 Enhancing the Weight of
Environmental Protection
Performance in Government
Assessment and Evaluation
The resolution of ecological and environmental
issues in river basins requires active participation
and supervision from the central government. Firstly,
the central government should augment the
significance of environmental performance in the
assessment and evaluation of provincial
governments. This can be achieved through the
implementation of measures such as "one vote veto"
and conducting interviews with government officials.
Furthermore, this emphasis on environmental
performance should be gradually extended to local
governments at the grassroots level. In addition,
preferential policies should be introduced to
incentivize local governments to increase their
investments in environmental protection. These
initiatives will serve to guide decision-making
behaviors at all levels of government towards
actions that facilitate ecological and environmental
improvement. Simultaneously, collaborative
development assessment indicators should be
established to encourage the participation of
governments at all levels in watershed
environmental protection. The central government
can also establish incentive contracts, such as the
river basin ecological and environmental protection
fund, which will be jointly funded by local
governments and the central government. This fund
will not only address the issue of insufficient funds
for ecological compensation but also serve as a
financing source for reward and punishment
mechanisms in environmental protection
assessments. It is important to note that the
assessment of environmental protection performance
and collaborative development is fundamentally a
subjective evaluation of ecological environment
improvement, rather than an objective demonstration.
Thus, achieving a broad consensus among all
stakeholders will guide the overall improvement of
the basin's ecological environment in a positive
direction.
5.2 Establishing Comprehensive
Environmental Protection
Coordination Institutions at the
River Basin Level
Efforts should be made to establish a comprehensive
environmental protection coordination body that
spans administrative river basins. This body should
comprise relevant ministries and provincial-level
governments, with dedicated functions for river
basin management, including planning, monitoring,
coordinating, and implementing major
environmental protection projects within the basins.
It is crucial to promptly define the ecological spatial
protection red line for river basins, clarify the roles
and responsibilities of local governments, and
prioritize environmental capital investment,
environmental protection capacity, and pollution
control in key river basins. These actions will
contribute to the shared long-term goal of
coordinated economic, social, and environmental
ICESCE 2024 - The International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering
126
development among the river basins. The
coordination body should explore the establishment
of mechanisms for environmental protection
cooperation and cooperation demonstration zones. It
should promote the protection of the environment in
economically developed areas while assisting less
developed areas in improving their ecological
environments. Exploring the feasibility of two-way
ecological compensation is also essential. For
instance, compensating downstream areas for
meeting water quality standards or compensating
upstream areas if they fail to meet the required
standards. Additionally, exploring mechanisms for
cross-border compensation, particularly in areas
with persistent air quality issues, can further
contribute to environmental improvement.
5.3 Enhancing Industrial
Restructuring Policies within
Resource and Environmental
Constraints
From an industrial perspective, the primary objective
of industrial structural adjustment is to mitigate the
ecological burden. Firstly, macro-control measures
should be optimized while considering resource and
environmental constraints, and industrial structure
adjustments should be made while accounting for
carrying capacity. National investment policies
should prioritize the rapid development of the
modern service industry and the ecological
environmental protection industry. Secondly, there
should be a strong emphasis on promoting cleaner
production, resource recycling, and upgrading
traditional industries and industrial parks. Lastly, it
is necessary to establish a unified threshold for
industrial environmental protection to prevent the
spatial transfer of polluting enterprises during the
relocation of non-capital functions and industrial
shifts. Industries that cause significant pollution and
damage to the water, air, and land environment
should be included in a planned manner on the list of
prohibited new developments within the river basin.
5.4 Gradually Establishing a Trading
Market for Drainage Basin
Emission Rights under
Environmental Control
As previously mentioned, enterprises play a crucial
role in implementing environmental protection
measures, and environmental control significantly
influences enterprise behavior. It is essential to
intensify administrative interventions and increase
the cost of environmental pollution for enterprises.
Moreover, enterprises can actively contribute to
improving the ecological environment. The
government can procure environmental protection
services from enterprises to enhance the
effectiveness of environmental protection funds
utilization. To facilitate this, it is advisable to guide
the establishment of a trading market for drainage
basin emission rights, controlling pollution levels
within a predetermined limit. Each enterprise within
the basin would be allocated specific emission
credits. If an enterprise exceeds its emission limit, it
would be required to purchase additional emission
quotas from the market. Conversely, enterprises with
effective environmental protection measures and
surplus emission credits can sell their excess quotas
in the market. This approach encourages enterprises
to strengthen their environmental protection
capabilities and reduce pollution.
5.5 Enhancing Environmental Law
Enforcement at the Grassroots
Level
To effectively implement environmental protection
measures at all levels of government, it is crucial to
address the shortcomings in environmental law
enforcement teams at the community level. This can
be achieved by allocating sufficient resources for
personnel and funding, enhancing technical skills,
and strengthening overall law enforcement capacity.
For instance, in accordance with the new
Environmental Law, governments at or above the
county level should establish public monitoring and
early warning mechanisms for environmental
pollution while formulating corresponding early
warning plans. Considering the uncertainty
surrounding the ecological environment and its
public goods nature, procedures for public
supervision and information disclosure should be
further improved. It is important to involve
stakeholders such as representatives of NPC
deputies, environmental law enforcement officers,
experts, lawyers, judges, enterprises, media,
environmental organizations, volunteers, and other
relevant parties in the demonstration and
decision-making processes regarding significant
ecological and environmental protection issues.
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
127
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The research work was greatly supported by
Research and Development Fund Project of
China
Institute of Geo-Environment Monitoring:
Research on Geoscience Knowledge graph for the
Improvement of Land Spatial Governance
Capability.
REFERENCES
Fu Y, 2021. Exploration on the Supervision Mechanism of
"Non-agriculturization" and "Non-grain Production"
of Cultivated Land in China——Based on Survey of
Ningxia Hui Autonomous Region. Natural Resource
Economics of China, 34(10): 4-11.
Zhang ZM, 2022. Suggestions for Implementing
Differentiated Policies in the field of Natural
Resources for Rural Revitalization——A Research
Report from Guizhou. Natural Resource Economics of
China, 35(02): 57-66.
Zu J, 2021. Evaluation on the Implementation of the 13th
Five-Year Plan for Land and Resources from the
Public Perspective. Land and Resources Information,
(11): 23-28.
Zu J, 2021. Challenges and Strategies of Cultivated Land
Protection in the BohaiRim Economic Zone in the
Post-pandemic Era. Land and Resources Information,
(12): 12-17.
Kong SJ, 2021. Research Progress of Economic
Compensation for Cultivated Land Protection. Land
and Resources Information, (09): 29-34.
Li LQ, 2021. Analysis of Spatial-temporal Variation
Characteristics and Driving Forces of Cultivated Land
in Guilin. Land and Resources Information, (06):
18-26.
Zhang JH, 2022. Research on the Spatial Pattern of
Cultivated Land Grade in the Coastal Plain——A
Case Study of Huanghua City of Hebei Province.
Natural Resource Economics of China, 35(03): 38-44.
Wu SM, 2022. Strengthening the "Trinity" Protection of
Cultivated Land in the New Era——Based on the
Innovation Practice of Jiangsu Province. Natural
Resource Economics of China, 35(01): 50-56,89.
Zhang X, 2021. Problems and Suggestions for Cultivated
Land Protection under the New Development
Trend——Thoughts on the Construction of
Supervision System for Cultivated land Protection.
Land and Resources Information, (12): 5-11.
Luo Y, 2021. Research on the Estimation of Asset Value
of Cultivated Land Resource in Sichuan Province.
Natural Resource Economics of China, 34(03):51-57.
Li X, 2021. Dynamic Analysis of Natural Capital Based
on Improved Three-dimensional Ecological
Footprint——Taking the Resource-exhausted City
Xuzhou City a san example. Natural Resource
Economics of China, 34(05): 24-31,88.
Hu HJ, 2017. Comments on Land Reclamation Research
under the Merger of “Two Cases” Based on the
Journal Literature Statistics from 1996 to 2016. Metal
Mine, (12): 147-152.
Hong WH, 2021. Study on the Distribution and
Influencing Factors of Selenium Based on the
Geochemical Method of Land Quality: A Case Study
of Tongren Area. Metal Mine, (12): 160-168.
Han ST, 2021. Multifunction Evaluation and Diagnosis of
Obstacle Factors of Cultivated Land in Shaanxi
Province. Land and Resources Information, (12):
23-30.
Du YT, 2021. Practice and Exploration of Mine-Land
Integration in Yixing City. Modern Mining, 37(05):
6-10.
Zhou W, 2021. International Experience Insights on
Cultivated Land Ecological Protection and
Compensation——Based on the Common
Agricultural Policy of EU. Natural Resource
Economics of China, 34(08): 37-43.
Lu S, 2021. Method Research and System Design on
Rectification of Building Houses By Occupying
Cultivated Land Indiscriminately. Land and Resources
Informatization, (02): 48-53.
Zhang GH, 2022. Main Causes and Mechanism for the
Natural Oasis Degeneration in the Lower Reaches of
Northwest Inland Basins. Hydrogeology and
Engineering Geology, 49(05): 1-11.
Yang L, 2021. Study on Adjustment Price Calculation of
Supplementary Cultivated Land in Xinjiang Uygur
Autonomous Region. Land and Resources
Information, (08): 32-38.
Qin JH, 2021. Sensitivity Evaluation of Cultivated Land
From a Perspective of “Agricultural Production-Urban
Development-Ecological Maintenance” Based on GIS.
Journal of Henan Polytechnic University(Natural
Science), 40(04): 78-88.
Ye SS, 2019. Ecological Environmental Cost Accounting
of Mining Area Based on the Green Mine: A Case
from a Mining Area in the North China Plain. Metal
Mine, (04): 168-174.
Yuan RX, 2021. Evaluation of Shallow Geothermal
Energy Resources in The Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei Plain
Based on Land Use. Journal of Groundwater Science
and Engineering, 9(02): 29-139.
Guo H, 2020. Research Progress on the Soil Vapor
Extraction. Journal of Groundwater Science and
Engineering, 8(01): 57-66.
Wang CG, 2022. The Analysis and Evaluation on the
Features of the Heavy Metals in Coal Mining Soil in
the Middle Reaches of the Yellow River. Mining
Safety &Environmental Protection, 49(05): 124-130.
Kim Y, 2022. Spatial Variation and Storage
Characteristics of Soil Nitrogen in a Small Watershed
in Danjiangkou Reservoir Area. Journal of Henan
Polytechnic University (Natural Science), 41(05):
87-95.
Yu Y, 2022. Applications of 3D Laser Scanning
Technology in The Extraction of Vegetation
ICESCE 2024 - The International Conference on Environmental Science and Civil Engineering
128
Parameters. Journal of Henan Polytechnic
University(Natural Science), 41(04): 51-57.
Yang C, 2021. Geochemical Characteristics and Its
Influencing Factors of Soil Selenium in Xiuwen
County,Guizhou Province. Modern Mining, 37(03):
23-26,34.
Shi SH, 2022. Heavy Metal Migration and Soil Pollution
Assessment in an Intensive Mining Area in the
Southwest China. Metal Mine, (02): 194-200.
Zhang PP, 2020. Effects of Coal Mining Subsidence on
Soil Aggregates and Organic Carbon. Metal Mine,
(12): 203-209.
Xie FF, 2021. Spatial Variation of Soil Properties and
Crop Response in Mining Subsidence area. Journal of
Henan Polytechnic University(Natural Science),
40(04): 89-97.
Yang HF, 2022. Assessment of Water level Threshold for
Groundwater Restoration and Over-exploitation
Remediation the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei Plain. Journal
of Groundwater Science and Engineering, 10(02):
113-127.
Wang N, 2021. Mine Environment Investigation and
Research Based on Remote Sensing Technology: A
Case Study of the Jidong Iron Mine. Metal Mine, (10):
192-198.
Yu HS, 2021. Research on Ecological Protection and
Restoration of Abandoned Open-pit Mine——Based
on the Ecological Restoration Project of Kadingshan
Mining Area. Land and Resources Information, (08):
50-56.
Zhao YW, 2020. Finite-Difference Model of Land
Subsidence Caused by Cluster Loads in Zhengzhou,
China. Journal of Groundwater Science and
Engineering, 8(01): 43-56.
Liu M, 2021. Comprehensive Evaluation on the
Ecological Function of Groundwater in the Shiyang
River Watershed. Journal of Groundwater Science and
Engineering, 9(04): 326-340.
LI WY, 2019. Numerical Simulation and Land Subsidence
Control for Deep Foundation Pit Dewatering of
Longyang Road Station on Shanghai Metro Line 18.
Journal of Groundwater Science and Engineering,
7(2): 133-144.
Zhou NQ, 2019. Characteristics of the Main Inorganic
Nitrogen Accumulation in Surface Water and
Groundwater of Wetland Succession Zones. Journal of
Groundwater Science and Engineering, 7(2): 173-181.
Zhang Y, 2022. Selection of Pioneer Plants for Repairing
Limestone High and Steep Slopes in North China. The
Chinese Journal of Geological Hazard and Control,
33(05): 109-118.
Li B, 2021. Preliminary Investigation on the Soil
Environment of a Farmland Polluted by Tailings.
Modern Mining, 37(12): 31-34.
Dang XY, 2021. The Relationship between Groundwater
and Natural Vegetation in QaidamBasin. Journal of
Groundwater Science and Engineering, 9(04):
341-349.
Dang YX, 2022. Discussion on the Top-level Design and
Optimization of the System of Cultivated Land
Requisition-Compensation Balance. Natural Resource
Economics of China, 35(06): 43-48,88.
Cheng CS, 2021. Study on the Cultivated Land Quality
Grade Evaluation of Comprehensive Management of
Substandard Forest Land——A Case Study of the
Land Development Project of 5 Villages. Land and
Resources Information, (12): 18-22.
Yu SK, 2022. Research on Comprehensive Zoning of
Cultivated Land in Low Mountainsand Hills——A
Case Study of Dexing City. Natural Resource
Economics of China, 35(03): 30-37,44.
Niu Y, 2021. Spatial-Temporal Evolution Pattern of Land
Use Transition and Changesin Ecosystem Service
Value in Huaihai Economic Zone. Land and
Resources Information, (04): 37-45.
Shima Nasiri, 2022. Determination of Water Balance
Equation Components in Irrigated Agricultural
Watersheds Using SWAT and MODFLOW models:
A case study of Samalqan plain in Iran. Journal of
Groundwater Science and Engineering, 10(01): 44-56.
Liu QS, 2021. Temporal and Spatial Changes of
Landscape Pattern And Analysis of Ecosystem Service
Value in Rocky Desertification Comprehensive
Control Area. Land and Resources Informatization,
(04): 53-59.
Xu J, 2021. Impacts of Land Use Change on Value of
Ecosystem Services in the Zuoyoujiang River Basin of
Guangxi. Land and Resources Information, (06): 8-17.
Wei P, 2022. Ecological Restoration Model and Existing
Problems Analysis of Legacy Abandoned Mine in the
Trunk Stream and Tributaries of the Yangtze River: a
Case Study of Sichuan Province. Metal Mine, (09):
209-215.
Deng XB, 2021. Discussion on the Realization Path of
Cultivated Land Protection in County level Territorial
Space Planning——A Case Study of Guizhou
Province. Land and Resources Information, (04):
46-50.
Wei C, 2021. Research on Spatio-Temporal Variation
Rules of Land Use Based on Association Rules
Method——A Case Study of Guangxi Zhuang
Autonomous Region. Land and Resources
Informatization, (01): 30-37.
Yuan SH, 2021. Study on Multifunctional Evaluation of
Cultivated Land in Puyang China. Land and Resources
Information, (02): 30-38.
Design of Ecological Environmental Protection Incentive Model: Based on Game Theory and from the Perspective of Collusion
129