Research on the Strategy and Social Effect of Firm’s Public Welfare
Marketing
Lei Wang
School of Economics Shandong University, Jinan, Shandong, China
Keywords: Public Welfare Marketing, The Proportion Of Income Donation, Product Quality, Firm’s Strategy, Social
Effect.
Abstract: Since the outbreak of covid-19, the public welfare marketing has been more and more extensive. In view of
this, we first establish a theoretical model to study whether two firms producing different quality products
participate in public welfare marketing and how to maximize the total donation. Firstly, whether a firm
participates in public welfare marketing depends on both the product quality and the proportion of income
donation; secondly, public welfare marketing may increase corporate profits and will certainly improve social
welfare; thirdly, in order to maximize the total donation, the optimal donation proportion must be a small
value. Then, we empirically test our theoretical prediction by capturing the marketing data of solid state in T-
mall. Based on research conclusions, we propose several suggestions for firms, government and public welfare
organizations in the end.
1 INTRODUCTION
In January 2020, the covid-19 spread rapidly in our
country. Hubei, as the hardest-hit area of the
epidemic, is in high shortage of medical resources.
For this reason, many firms have generously donated
money and materials. In addition to direct donations,
a lot of firms also raise funds for the affected areas by
public welfare marketing. For example, on February
6th, 2020, Shiseido Group launched the "Relay of
Love Project", setting 1% of Asia's marketing
(estimated to be RMB 130 million) as a charity fund
to provide material support to Wuhan. On February
10th, the IT training company Source Code Era
launched a public welfare course, and donated
income to fight the covid-19. On February 13th, the
China Headquarters of the American Serta Group
launched the "Surta Angels in Action" charity
marketing plan and donated 1,842,004 yuan to the
Wuhan Charity Federation.
Although public welfare marketing is very
common, especially in the event of major
emergencies, there are three academic problems that
are not clear: first, when there are differences in
product quality, are firms willing to participate in
public welfare marketing? On the one hand,
participating in public welfare marketing can
improve the corporate image and improve consumers'
brand recognition, which helps to improve product
pricing power and corporate profits. On the other
hand, participating in public welfare marketing
means that part of the marketing revenue must be
donated, which means the loss of profits. Therefore,
when there are differences in product quality, it is
difficult to predict the positive and negative impact of
participating in public welfare marketing on firm
profits. Second, how does public welfare marketing
affect social welfare? This issue is directly related to
whether the government should advocate public
welfare marketing. Third, in order to maximize the
total public welfare donation, how to set the optimal
proportion of income donation? This problem not
only directly affects the willingness of firms to
participate in public welfare marketing, but also
indirectly affects the amount of donations finally
raised, thus affecting the degree of assistance to
donors, and even the degree of prevention and control
of major disasters.
Our research is closely related to the literature in
the field of public welfare marketing. The existing
literature is mainly divided into three categories. The
first kind of literature studies the impact of public
welfare marketing on consumer behavior, and finds
that consumers prefer to choose products for public
welfare marketing, and the corporate image (Barone,
Wang, L.
Research on the Strategy and Social Effect of Firm’s Public Welfare Marketing.
DOI: 10.5220/0011162300003440
In Proceedings of the International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management (BDEDM 2022), pages 105-110
ISBN: 978-989-758-593-7
Copyright
c
2022 by SCITEPRESS Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
105
et al, 2000), consumer characteristics (Grau, Folse,
2007), the correlation between products and public
welfare matters (Pracejus, Olsen, 1992) will affect
consumers' purchase decisions. The second kind of
literature studies the impact of public welfare
marketing on public welfare organizations and
participating firms. Although public welfare
organizations can raise money, they may lose their
reputation due to bad brands (Andreasen 1996), and
participating firms may increase their income due to
public welfare marketing (Lafferty, Goldsmith,
2005). The third kind of literature focuses on the
strategy of public welfare marketing. Arora and
Henderson (Henderson, 2007) compared the
promotion effects of public welfare marketing,
discounts and return of commissions. Pracejus et al.
(Pracejus, et al, 2003) studied whether public welfare
donation should be in the form of donation amount or
donation proportion, Krishna and Rajan (Krishna,
Rajan, 2009) studied how firms should choose
products for public welfare marketing. Although the
existing literature is of great reference value, these
documents don’t consider the quality differences
between firm products, so they do not consider the
impact of product quality on firms' willingness to
participate in public welfare marketing and their
profits, and it is impossible to analyze how product
quality affects the social welfare effect of public
welfare marketing, which is the focus of this paper.
Therefore, compared with the existing literature,
this paper may have three contributions: first, we
build a duopoly competition model with different
product quality, and compare the profit changes
before and after firms participate in public welfare
marketing. Our research conclusions can provide
decision-making basis for firms to participate in
public welfare marketing. Second, we calculated and
compared the total amount of public welfare
donations and the corresponding social welfare level
under different conditions, and analyzed the impact
of public welfare marketing and donation proportion
on the total amount of donations and social welfare.
Our research conclusion can not only provide a
theoretical basis for public welfare organization
departments to set the optimal donation proportion, it
can also provide reference for government
departments to encourage public welfare marketing.
Thirdly, we also captured the marketing data of solid-
state drives (abbreviated as SSD in the
following part)
in Tmall and empirically tested the relationship
between public welfare marketing and product
quality found in our theoretical analysis. These
conclusions can provide empirical evidence for
encouraging public welfare marketing during major
public health and safety events in China, and have
better policy implications and practical
enlightenment.
2 THEORETICAL MODEL
Suppose there are two firms competing for output in
the market - firm 1 and firm 2, which produce product
1 and product 2 respectively, and the quality of the
two products is 1 and
s
,
1s >
. In order to simplify the
analysis, we assume that the marginal cost and fixed
cost of the two firms are zero. If the firm
i
does not
participate in public welfare marketing, the
consumer's evaluation of its product is the quality
level of the product; If firms
i
participate in public
welfare marketing, consumers' evaluation of the
quality of their products will increase due to the
enhancement of consumers' emotional identity,
which is denoted as
()
0ΔΔ>
. However, firms
i
need to donate part of their marketing revenue to
public welfare undertakings according to the income
donation proportion
r
set in advance by public
welfare organizations or public welfare sponsors.
Assuming
Δ
is relatively small, this hypothesis one
is to ensure that when only low-quality products
participate in public welfare marketing, their overall
quality evaluation is lower than that of high-quality
products, that is, to meet
1
s
<
; the second is to
ensure that when only high-quality products
participate in public welfare marketing, low-quality
products will not be squeezed out of the market. The
consumer's utility function is
i
Usp
θ
=−
.
θ
represents the preference parameter of consumers for
the product, which is evenly distributed in
[0,1]
.
i
s
represents the consumer's evaluation or
"confirmation" of product quality.
The sequence of the problem as follows: in the
first stage, two firms simultaneously choose whether
to participate in charity marketing and compete for
output; in the second stage, consumers determine the
quality of the product after observing whether the
company is conducting charity marketing. And
decide whether to buy products and which products
to buy. We use backwards induction to solve the
equilibrium of the problem.
When neither firm carries out public welfare
marketing, we can get the output, price and profit of
the firm by solving the problem of profit
maximization.
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
106
1
41
NN
s
q
s
=
,
2
21
41
NN
s
q
s
=
,
1
41
NN
s
p
s
=
,
()
2
21
41
NN
ss
p
s
=
()
2
1
2
41
NN
s
s
π
=
,
()
()
2
2
2
12
41
NN
s
s
π
=
When firm 1 carries out public welfare marketing,
we can get the output, price and profit of the firm by
solving the problem of profit maximization.
1
41
RN
s
q
s
=
−−Δ
,
2
21
41
RN
s
q
s
−−Δ
=
−−Δ
()
1
1
41
RN
s
p
s
=
−−Δ
,
()
2
21
41
RN
ss
p
s
−−Δ
=
−−Δ
()( )
()
2
1
2
11
41
RN
s
rs
π
−+Δ
−−Δ
=
,
()
()
2
2
2
12
41
RN
s
s
s
π
−+
Δ
−Δ
=
When firm 2 carries out public welfare marketing,
we can get the output, price and profit of the firm by
solving the problem of profit maximization.
1
441
NR
s
q
s
=
,
2
441
221
NR
s
q
s
+
Δ−
=
1
441
NR
s
p
s
=
,
()( )
2
221
441
NR
ss
p
s
+ Δ−
=
()
()
2
1
2
441
NR
s
s
π
=
,
()
()( )
()
2
2
2
221
1
441
NR
ss
r
s
π
+ Δ−
=−
When both firms carry out public welfare
marketing,
we can get the output, price and profit of
the firm by solving the problem of profit
maximization.
1
431
RR
s
q
s
=
,
2
21
431
RR
s
q
s
+Δ−
=
()()
1
1
431
RR
s
p
s
=
,
()( )
2
21
431
RR
s
s
s
p
+
+
Δ
=
Δ−
()
()( )
()
2
1
2
1
1
431
RR
s
r
s
π
=−
,
()
()( )
()
2
2
2
21
1
431
RR
ss
r
s
π
+Δ−
=−
Proposition 1: Under equilibrium conditions,
whether the two firms carry out public welfare
marketing is related to the proportion of revenue
donation. Specifically, there are three critical points
*
1
r
,
*
2
r
and
*
3
r
,which satisfy
***
123
01rrr<<<<
,
(1) if
*
1
(0, ]rr
, both firms carry out public
welfare marketing;
(2) if
**
12
(, ]rrr
, firm 2 carries out public welfare
marketing;
(3) if
**
23
(, ]rrr
, firm 1 carries out public welfare
marketing;
(4) if
*
3
(,1]rr
, neither firm carries out public
welfare marketing.
Proposition 1 has two implications: first, in order
to encourage both firms to participate in public
welfare marketing, the donation proportion must be
set relatively small, that is
*
1
(0, ]rr
; Otherwise, If
the donation ratio is high (more than
*
1
r
), at least one
firm does not participate in public welfare marketing,
or even two firms do not participate in public welfare
marketing. Second, the willingness of firms to
participate in public welfare marketing depends on
both the proportion of revenue donation and the
quality of their products. Therefore, we get a
theoretical conclusion to be empirically tested: if the
proportion of donation is low, the higher the quality
of products, the more willing they are to carry out
public welfare marketing; however, if the proportion
of donation is high, the lower the quality of products,
the more willing they are to carry out public welfare
marketing.
Proposition 2: Compared with not participating
in public welfare marketing, the profits of firms
participating in public welfare marketing may
increase or decrease.
Specifically, there are two
critical values
1
r
and
2
r
,which satisfy
*
121
0 rr r<<<

,
(1) If
*
1
(0, ]rr
, both firms participate in public
welfare marketing, there may be three situations
about the profits of the firms compared with the both
firms do not participate in public welfare marketing:
if
1
(0, ]rr
, the profits of both firms increased; if
12
(, ]rrr

, the profit of firm 1 increased and the
profit of firm 2 decreased; if
*
21
(, ]rrr
, the profits
of both firms decreased.
(2)
If
**
13
(, ]rrr
, compared with the two firms
that do not participate in public welfare marketing,
the profits of firms that participate in public welfare
marketing increase and the profits of firms that do not
participate in public welfare marketing decrease.
Comparing the total social welfare in four
situations, we draw the following conclusions.
Proposition 3: Compared with the two firms that
do not carry out public welfare marketing, public
Research on the Strategy and Social Effect of Firm’s Public Welfare Marketing
107
welfare marketing improves social welfare, and the
social welfare is the largest when both firms carry out
public welfare marketing.
From the perspective of firms, it can be seen from
proposition 2 that compared with not participating in
public welfare marketing, the profits of firms
participating in public welfare marketing may
increase or decrease, but the profits of firms are only
part of the gross income of the industry, and the other
part of the gross income of the industry is public
welfare donation. Because social welfare includes
two parts, namely, industry gross income and
consumer surplus, our analysis shows that public
welfare marketing increase the gross income of the
whole industry and consumer surplus due to
enhancing consumers' "identity", so public welfare
marketing improve social welfare; Moreover, when
both firms carry out public welfare marketing, the
social welfare reaches the maximum.
3 EMPIRICAL TEST
3.1 Materials and Methods
In the empirical test, we chose SSD as the research
object mainly based on two reasons: firstly, because
the horizontal difference of SSD samples is small, we
can try to avoid the interference of other factors other
than product quality; secondly, because products of
SSD are relatively simple, there are clear indicators
to measure the quality difference between samples.
Since the indicators such as commodity quality and
whether commodities participate in public welfare
marketing are less affected by time changes, we
conduct an empirical study using the SSD data of
Tmall, and capture product information through data
capture software. Due to the failure of commodity ID
and the fact that a single commodity ID corresponds
to multiple commodities, we obtained 400 valid
samples through manual screening.
We take whether the product participates in public
welfare marketing (denoted as y) as the explained
variable. The explained variable is a virtual variable.
If the firm carries out public welfare marketing, it is
recorded as 1, otherwise it is recorded as 0. The core
explanatory variable we choose is product quality.
For SSD, the larger the space, the more data can be
stored, so the hard disk space is an important indicator
of their quality, that is, the higher the quality of SSD,
the larger space it has. The threshold variable is the
proportion of public welfare donations, and the
control variables include monthly marketing,
popularity, cumulative reviews and price, service,
logistics, description and rank.
The hypothesis we want to test is that if the
proportion of public welfare donations is low, the
higher the quality of products, the more willing they
are to carry out public welfare marketing; if the
proportion of public welfare donations is high, the
lower the quality of products, the more willing to
carry out public welfare marketing. Therefore, we use
threshold regression model for empirical research.
The regression equation is as follows:
()
01
ln
1
P
Quality I r
P
ββ γ
=+
()
23i
Quality I r X
βγβ
ε
+⋅ > + +
Where,
r
represents threshold variable,
γ
represents unknown threshold value,
()
I
represents
index function,
i
X
represents control variable and
ε
represents random disturbance term.
3.2 Results & Discussion
The regression results of sample data are shown in
Table 3. It can be seen from table 1 that when the
proportion of public welfare donation is less than or
equal to 0.0266667%, the higher the quality of
products, the more willing they are to carry out public
welfare marketing; When the proportion of public
welfare donation is greater than 0.0266667%, the
lower the quality of products, the more willing they
are to carry out public welfare marketing. The
regression results can verify our previous theoretical
expectations. In terms of control variables, the price
and logistics scores are significant before and after
the threshold, specifically: (1) When the proportion
of public welfare donation is low, the products with
lower price are more willing to carry out public
welfare marketing; when the proportion of public
welfare donation is high, the products with higher
price are more willing to carry out public welfare
marketing. The reason is that under other conditions,
low price means that the profit space of products is
small. If the proportion of donation is too high, it is
not conducive to the profit maximization goal of low-
cost products When the proportion of profit donation
is low, low-price products are willing to participate in
public welfare marketing; (2) Products with low
logistics scores are more willing to demonstrate their
product quality through public welfare marketing.
When the proportion of public welfare donations
increases, products with lower logistics scores are
more willing to participate in public welfare
marketing. The reason is that under other conditions,
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
108
consumers are less likely to choose products with low
logistics scores, and public welfare marketing helps
to improve consumers' evaluation of products.
Therefore, products with low logistics scores are
more willing to participate in public welfare
marketing.
Table 1: Results of regression.
threshold value
0.0266667%
γ
=
r
γ
r
γ
>
Quality
0.000139576***
3.005
-0.000463083*
-1.8017
Price
-0.000053497**
-1.968
0.000354339***
3.976
Marketing
-0.000034391
-0.652
-
0.006452529***
-3.938
Review
0.0000048187
0.4534
-0.001450056
-1.3232
Popularity
-0.0000032302
-0.3761
0.000150267
1.2034
Description
0.504443912
0.9623
0.692010066
0.693
Service
0.586749092
1.292
-1.32822055
-0.6409
Logistics
-1.16531424**
-2.4667
-5.70283681**
-2.8019
Rank
0.000017266
0.0947
-.000942945**
-2.0036
Note: ***, **, * respectively represents significant at 1%,
5% and 10% significant levels; the values in parentheses
are Z statistics.
4 CONCLUSIONS
Our study finds that whether a firm participates in
public welfare marketing depends on both the product
quality and the proportion of income donation; public
welfare marketing may increase the profits of firms
and will certainly improve social welfare; in order to
maximize the total donation, the optimal donation
proportion must be a relatively small value. The
conclusions have some policy implications. Firstly,
firms should actively formulate public welfare
marketing strategies according to their product
quality. Specifically, in order to achieve the double
"harvest" of corporate reputation and corporate
profits, firms selling high-quality products should try
to choose public welfare projects with a low donation
proportion; however, firms selling low-quality
products should try to choose public welfare projects
with a high proportion of donations. Secondly, public
welfare marketing can not only benefit industry
profits and public welfare undertakings as a whole,
but also increase consumer surplus, so as to improve
social welfare. Moreover, if the proportion of income
donation can be set appropriately, it can meet the
multi-objective requirements of firms, public welfare,
consumers and social welfare at the same time, and
engage in a win-win situation. Thus, government
departments should vigorously advocate public
welfare marketing, especially in the current situation
of fighting with covid-19. Finally, for public welfare
organizations, in the critical period of epidemic
prevention, the goal can be adjusted to maximize
public welfare donations, and an appropriate donation
proportion can be set to encourage more firms to
participate in public welfare marketing, so as to better
integrate public welfare forces and contribute to the
epidemic stricken areas. With the gradual
improvement of the epidemic situation, public
welfare organizations should fully consider the
interests of firms and appropriately reduce the
donation proportion, so as to achieve a win-win
situation between public welfare undertakings and
firm profits.
REFERENCES
Andreasen, A.R. (1996). Profits for nonprofits: Find a
corporate partner. Harvard Business Review. 74(6), 47-
50.
Arora, N., Henderson, T. (2007). Embedded premium
promotion: Why it works and how to make it more
effective. Marketing Science. 26(4), 514-531.
Barone, M.J., Miyazaki, A.D., Taylor, K.A. (2000). The
influence of cause-related marketing on consumer
choice: does one good turn deserve another? Journal of
The Academy of Marketing Science. 28(2), 248-262.
Grau, S.L., Folse, J.A.G. (2007). Cause-related Marketing
(CRM)-The influence of donation proximity and
message-framing cues on the less-involved consumer.
Journal of Advertising. 36(4), 19-33.
Krishna, A., Rajan, U. (2009). Cause marketing: Spillover
effects of cause-related products in a product portfolio.
Management Science. 55(9), 1469-1485.
Lafferty, B.A., Goldsmith, R.E. (2005). Cause-brand
alliances: Does the cause help the brand or does the
brand help the cause. Journal of Business Research.
58(4), 423-429.
Pracejus, J.W., Olsen, G.D. (2004). The role of brand/cause
fit in the effectiveness of cause-related marketing
campaigns. Journal of Business Research. 57(6), 635-
640.
Pracejus, J.W., Olsen, G.D., Brown, N.R. (2003). On the
Prevalence and Impact of Vague Quantifiers in the
Advertising of Cause-related Marketing (CRM).
Journal of Advertising. 32(4), 19-28.
Research on the Strategy and Social Effect of Firm’s Public Welfare Marketing
109
APPENDIX
22 2 3
*
1
22223
16 32 16
1 8 16 7 24 16 8 32 16
ss
r
ss s s s
−Δ + Δ Δ + Δ + Δ
=
−+ Δ+ Δ+ Δ+Δ+ Δ+Δ
()
() ( )( )
(
)
() ()
()
2
43 2 2 2 3
*
2
2
22
64 64 1 1 4 10 7 4 2 3
18 2 3
ss s s
r
sss
Δ + Δ− + Δ Δ+Δ − −Δ+ Δ
=
+ + Δ− −Δ
()
()( )
2
*
3
2
16 1
114
s
r
s
Δ−Δ
=
()()
()()
2342 233
1
2345 2342 233
1 8 24 40 32 2 12 36 44
12 52 96 64 1 14 72 160 128 2 21 72 80
ss s s ss s a
r
s
ssss ss s s sss a
Δ− + − + +Δ−+ − + +Δ
=
+ + + + − + +
()( )
()()
242 233
2
23 4 2 3 4 2 3 3
29 16 169 32
8 16 2 15 24 16 1 6 32
ss s ss s a
r
s
ss ss ss ss a
Δ−+ +Δ−+ +Δ
=
−+ +Δ− + + +Δ+ +Δ
BDEDM 2022 - The International Conference on Big Data Economy and Digital Management
110