Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The
Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory
Suripto Suripto
1,2
, Firmansyah Firmansyah
1
and FX. Sugiyanto
1
1
Faculty of Economics and Business, Diponegoro University
2
Faculty of Economics, Ahmad Dahlan University
suriptobantul@gmail.com
Keywords: Solow Growth Model, Educational Investment, Poverty, Poverty line.
Abstract: From the economic aspect, the level of education is believed to reduce poverty by improving skills that can
influence the household income. Meantime, the poor with skills produced from formal and non-formal
education will be rescued from market price shocks. By using the perspective of the production function with
adopts Solow's growth model technology, this study analyses how the formal and non-formal educations
affect income levels, and subsequently consumption. With certain lines of consumption, a household is
classified as poor or not poor so that it can be examined the probability of household being either poor or non-
poor influenced by formal and non-formal education. This research is applied on Special Province of
Yogyakarta and is expected to explain one aspect of poverty behaviour in Special Province of Yogyakarta.
1 INTRODUCTION
Poverty is a development effort to create prosperity
through the fulfilment of human needs. Failure to
meet basic needs can occur due to a market and re-
quires the government's side to overcome it.
According to Word Bank (2001), poverty is the
understanding, or inability to achieve, a generally
accepted standard of living.
In 2012 the Special Province of Yogyakarta
experienced the worst level of poverty in the bottom
25 of 33 provinces) but has a very good Human
Development Index (HDI). An interesting finding in
D.I.Yogyakarta Province shows that high HDI is not
followed by low poverty rates.
Good HDI will impact productive communities
and subsequently depends on economic growth and
declining unemployment. The improvement of HDI
will be followed by economic growth and declining
unemployment rate. HDI can encourage the
improvement of human resources and in turn, will
result in economic growth and decline in
unemployment.
Improving the quality of human resources can
occur with cheap investment educators. The impact of
education on poverty is examined by (Grimm, 2005),
found to be a direct effect of education and income,
depending on the choice of employment and house-
hold composition. Education is an efficient way to
reduce poverty and fairer inequality
The cause of someone being poor is an interesting
study to observe. According to Barnes (2005), the
globalisation resulted in industrialisation shifting
from manufacturing industry to service industry, and
there was a reduction of manpower with low human
resources replaced by high human resource work-
force. Barnes (2005) sees that the main factor causing
poverty is the depletion of human resources of the
poor.
The solution to poverty reduction is done by
increasing the human resources of the poor.
Investment in education will affect the ability of the
poor to earn income. Rising incomes will reduce the
number of poor families. Bhaumik and Banik (2009)
found that human capital improvements are strongly
related to the resilience of the poor to obtain
permanent income. Increasing formal education to the
poor will improve skills and sensitivity to external
changes. This sensitivity will avoid the loss of their
income. Poor people with more intensive formal
724
Suripto, S., Firmansyah, F. and Sugiyanto, F.
Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory.
In Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Economic Education and Entrepreneurship (ICEEE 2017), pages 724-731
ISBN: 978-989-758-308-7
Copyright © 2017 by SCITEPRESS Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
skills will be spared from the failure of price-level
shocks in the output market.
Theoretically, poverty is influenced by low
productivity. A person's productivity level can be
influenced by the level of education, real knowledge
and skills and the level of health. The higher
education that is graduated and the longer they go to
education will have better skills and will have an
impact on higher incomes and have a lower chance of
becoming poor.
1.1 Solow Growth Model
It is assumed that the family is the smallest unit of
production of goods and services by using its
production factor in the form of capital and labour.
Capital consists of human capital and physical
capital.
The main assumptions of Solow's growth model
are; (I) the economy is closed for international
transactions, (ii) all stored output is invested, (iv)
perfect price flexibility and monetary neutrality (i) the
economy consists of one sector producing one type of
commodity that can be used for either investment or
consumption purposes; Apply and the economy al-
ways generates its potential output; (V) the rate of
technological progress, population growth, and the
rate of capital depreciation are all exogenously
determined.
Solow growth model is built based on two big
ideas namely production function and the equation of
model accumulation function. The production
function is assumed to follow the Cobb-Douglas
production function as follows (C. Jones, 1998),
(Romer, 2000), and the production function is based
on physical capital (K), Productivity Augmented
Labor (AL) and human capital (Jones) 1986):
1
),,(
tttt
LAHKALHKFY
(1)
α is worth between 0 and 1
0)(),(
'
ttt
eheh
(2)
1.2 The Impact of Education on Labor
Productivity
Education is one of the most important inputs to
produce human resources. Education produces a
stock of accumulated skills and experiences that make
workers more productive, (Bassetti, 2012). Trostel
(2004) suggests that the production function of
human capital increases at a low level of education
and declines at a high level of education. Trostel
(2004) concluded that the educational relationship
with labour productivity is non-linear and directly
related to the accumulation of human capital. In other
words, the production function of human capital has
a cubic form, which is a typical production function
used in the function of microeconomic production.
(Bassetti, 2008) States that education is the only
input that increases human capital. Education deals
with one's technological development capabilities.
Education will enable one to capture new
technologies and develop technology that will
ultimately increase production through increased
productivity (B. F. Jones, 2014). The process of the
occurrence of human capital depends on the time in
which the individual provides time for education. If
Lt is the population at time t in an economy, μ is the
time the individual chooses to work; it is the
willingness of the individual at time t who is willing
to invest his or her opinion for education. So the
model of individuals willing to invest in education is:
Solow's growth model emphasises the importance
of individual technology development from self-
development because of the stock of knowledge.
Knowledge stocks can occur from a person's
education. The advent of technology will result in the
depreciation of human capital stocks, because the
new technology will require new knowledge to
master the technology and will replace the old
knowledge possessed by someone. High technology
requires new knowledge and will leave the old
knowledge known as the effects of vice (vintage
effect). Technological advances affect the
improvement of knowledge and will increase the
demand for experts resulting in obsolete experts; the
ultimate impact will increase the demand for
individual education, known as the technical
depreciation effect (Bassetti, 2008).
If Eht is the effect that an individual obtains
because of the education obtained at time t, and t is
the depreciation of human capital due to the effects of
obsolescence at time t, then the model of human
capital accumulation through education is:
0)('
)(
t
tt
t
t
h
hEh
de
dh
(3)
The Meaning of Equation (3) is the effect of
individual educational investments on individual
stocks of capital determined by individual
productivity be-cause of education reduced by
depreciation due to the effects of knowledge
obsolescence.
Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory
725
By combining two equations (2) and (3) then it is
assumed that the stock of human capital is linearly
correlated with the depreciation of knowledge then
obtained:
)(
tt
t
t
ehEhe
de
dh
(4)
It is assumed that the productivity gained from the
educational investment will outweigh the effects of
obsolescence (E> σ) so that educational investment
affects the accumulation of individual knowledge.
The process of knowledge accumulation can be writ-
ten as follows:
)exp(
)exp(
t
t
t
EeE
EeE
h
(5)
Equation (5) means that the stock of knowledge
accumulation will depend on the individual choice of
the school and the knowledge stock is not
proportional to the time of the education.
His process of obtaining knowledge stock is the
aggregate sum of the individual activities in
conducting educational activities, so the equation of
accumulated knowledge stock is:
L
hLdihiA
0
,
(6)
Hi is the level of human capital owned by
individuals in period t, and is the average human
capital that all workers do. From equation (6) it is
known that the average stock of knowledge is
determined by the level of education, then based on
equations (5) and (6) can be obtained:
(7)
Where is the average level of education pursued
in a given region, and by the combination of
equations (6), equations (5), and equation (1) and
considering the size per effective labour obtained:
)exp(
)(
eEE
eEEp
ky
(8)
y
is the output per unit of effective labour and is
capital per effective labour, equation (8) shows that
education is the input resulting from the existence of
human capital education. Findings (C. I. Jones, 2001)
found that there is a positive relationship between
GDP growth and the level of education affecting the
growth of a country's output.
The per capita output is obtained by combining
equation (7), equation (8), and equation (5). If the
educational investment is, which means educational
investment per capita depends on the amount of time
to pursue education, then the equation is obtained:
1
)(Aheky
(9)
Total production will be influenced by the total
acquisition of knowledge A and the average length of
time for education. In the output growth equation
becomes:
kefAhyg ln)(ln)1(ln)(ln
(10)
The output growth is influenced by the growth of
knowledge due to education investment (
Ah
) and
the average growth of the school year and the growth
of physical investment per capita. The growth of
knowledge measured by Ah can be seen as the
residual variable (Bassetti, 2008), so output depends
on the level of education. The growth of output is
writ-ten:
T
ii
Xeyg
0
ln
(11)
The total productivity of a production function is
influenced by the average school year
e
of βi and the
control variable influencing the acquisition of
knowledge determined by external factors (
T
X
).
1.3 Research Model
Equation model 10 is used to explain the state of
poverty in the Special Province of Yogyakarta.
Assuming that the output produced by the family
follows equation 11, and all outputs obtained are used
to consume goods and services. The poverty rate in
this study was calculated using the head count index
method. Household poverty rate based on the poverty
line of Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS), the line of
papers is Rp 303,843.
The dependent variable is dummy variable that is
poor household and not poor so this research use
Cumulative Logistic Distribution Function (logit
model) that is:
P(Yi = 0/Xj) =
i
Z
e
Pi
1
1
1
(12)
Logit model (LYi) for empirical estimation
purposes, as follows:
LY
i
=
iij
i
i
X
p
p
**
0
1
ln
(13)
ICEEE 2017 - 2nd International Conference on Economic Education and Entrepreneurship
726
i
i
p
p
1
is an odds ratio that is defined as the ratio
of house-hold probability belonging to the poor
category of household probability belonging to the
non-poor category. The independent variable (Xi)
consists of the year of school variable and the control
variable.
Table 1: Independent variables.
Year of School Variable
MSEKO
:
Average length of school for all
household members in a year
IJAH1
:
The highest diploma owned by the
head of household, 1 if less than Senior
High School, 0 if the high school and
above.
Control variables
UR
:
Household size in person
UMUR
:
Age of head of household in the year.
PKR
:
Work of the head of household, 1 if
agriculture, 0 if non-agricultural.
SKR
:
Status of Occupation of the head of
household, 1 if informal, 0 if formal.
GEO3
:
Domestic area of residence, 1 if the
residence in the land area, 0 if the
residence in the other part.
MPKR
:
On average all household members
work in year
i
: Variable pester, β0: constant, βj: parameter coefficient
2 METHODS
Estimation of logit model using Maximum
Likelihood Estimator (MLE) because of logit model
is the nonlinear model in parameter and in variable
and data used is individual data, so probability value
is unknown (Gujarati, 2004). The logit model is then
tested individually (partially) by testing the Z test
statistic, testing the model as a whole (simultaneous)
with likelihood ratio test statistic (LR), and testing the
goodness of fit Goodness with McFadden R2
(R2McF). Interpretation of logit model will be
distinguished by variable type that is category
variable and numeric / continuous variable by looking
at odds ratio and Marginal effect.
The data used in this study is secondary data with
the main data derived from raw data Susenas D.I.
Yogyakarta in 2013, supplemented with and
supporting data including PDRB data, poverty data,
public welfare indicator data (inkesra), and economic
indicators. The sample numbered 3606 households.
2.1 Variable Operational Definition
Dependent variable (LYi) is household poverty status
in Special Province of Yogyakarta in the form of a
dummy variable, 1 if household falls into the poor
category and 0 if not poor. Definition of the
dependent variable and independent variable used in
this re-search are:
Household poverty status is absolute poverty,
households are said to be poor if their income is
not able to meet their minimum requirements. In
this study, it is said to be poor if household per
capita expenditure is below the poverty line of
Rp303,843 per capita per month.
Household size is the number of people living in
households six months or more, or who will be
living in households six months or more.
The age of the head of the household is the age
of a person of the household member who is
responsible for the daily needs of the household.
The work of the head of the household is the
type of household head's work which is
differentiated in the agricultural and non-
agricultural sectors.
Occupation status of head of household is the
status of employment of head of household
which is differentiated into non-formal (in-
formal) and formal status.
The territory of residence shall be the area of
residence of the household based on the
topography of the territory which is divided in-
to land and non-land areas.
The average length of school for all household
members is the number of years that all
household members take in formal education
which is calculated to the highest level of
education or the highest grade ever occupied.
The highest diploma of household head is the
highest certificate owned by the head of the
household based on the highest education that is
completed.
The average member of the working house-hold
is the average member of the working household
and will affect the household in-come level.
3 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
The determinant model of Special Province of
Yogyakarta in 2013 provides information that the size
of household heads, household heads, employment
status of head of households have a positive and
significant impact on household poverty status.
Variable area of residence, the average length of the
school of household members, the highest Owned by
Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory
727
the head of household, the average member of the
working household and the age of the household head
had a negative and significant effect on the household
poverty status (Table 2).
Table 2: Estimation result of determinant model household
poverty in special province of Yogyakarta Year 2013 (n =
3606).
Variable
Estimate
Zi
Odds
Ratio
Marginal
Effect
C*
-0.9526
-2.697
0.3857
-0.0722
IJAH*
-0.0489
-2.451
0.9523
-0.0037
MSEKO*
-0.2938
-12.17
0.7454
-0.0223
UR*
0.4420
12.749
1.5558
0.0335
UMUR**
-0.0069
-1.6986
0.9931
-0.0005
PKR*
0.7538
6.3125
2.1250
0.0571
SKR*
0.5323
3.6613
1.7028
0.0403
MPKR**
-0.3711
-1.766
0.6900
-0.0281
GEO3*
-0.4048
-3.3552
0.6671
-0.0307
R2McF
0,223584
LR statistic (10 df)
3,35228
Probability(LR stat)
0.000000
*, **, significant at the 5% significance level and 10%
Test Model individually in Table 2 by comparing
the Z value of statistics with Z table with the
significance level () of 0.05 or 0.10. The estimation
results indicate that the variables of household
members (UR), occupation of head of household
(PKR), employment status of head of household
(SKR), residence area (GEO3), average length of
member school of household (MSEKO) and diploma
(IJAH) has a significant and statistically significant
effect on the 5 per-cent significance level of
household poverty status in Special Province of
Yogyakarta. The average member of the working
household (MPKR) and the age of the household head
(UMUR) affect the household poverty status in D.I
Yogyakarta province with a significance level of 10
percent.
From the regression result, the estimated logit
model shows the LR statistic value of 718.5542. The
comparison of the statistical LR value with the table
value indicates that the LR value is considerably
larger than the value of the table at the 0.05
significance level. This means that statistically
independent variables together affect the probability
of household poverty in Special Province of
Yogyakarta.
Test the goodness of fit by looking at the value of
R2McF of 0.223584, which means that 22.36 percent
variation of household poverty status in Special
Province of Yogyakarta can be explained by the
variables in the model. This R2McF value is good for
cross-data (Kabananukye, et.all, 2004).
The household education variable in this study is
represented by the highest certificate owned by the
head of household (IJAH). The 2013 logit model
obtained that the highest certificate owned by the
head of household has a negative and significant
effect on the poor status of the household. Estimated
value of 0.048922 and odds ratio of 0.9523. This
means that every increase of one level of highest
education certificate owned by the head of household
head then the probability of the household into the
poor category will be 0.9523 times the house-hold
with lower education level. In other words, the higher
the diploma held by the head of household, the lower
the probability of the poor category of the household.
The marginal effect of the highest diploma variable
owned by the head of household is -0,0037, meaning
the chances of household entering into the poor
category will be reduced by 0.37 percent if the highest
certificate owned by the head of house-hold is
increased one level higher. This shows that education
plays an important role in the family to get out of
poverty. The higher the diploma held by the head of
the household will have a large stock of knowledge
and the productivity of the head of the household will
increase. The head of household responsible for the
fulfilment of the economic needs provided with
higher formal education will have an impact on
increasing the productivity, and the quality of output
produced so that the wages received will increase.
Households included in the poor category will be
smaller. The same statement that the education of the
head of the household negatively affects poverty by
the re-search of Ueda, et.al (2005: 11), (Guillaumont,
Guillaumont Jeanneney, & Wagner, 2017).
The variable of human resources (HR) in the
research was obtained by the average variable of
school length of the household member (SEKO). The
result of coefficient estimate shows that the average
length of the school of a member of the household has
significant influence with household risk to be poor.
The coefficients of the MSEKO variable are -
0.293816 with the odd ratio of 0.7454. This means
that every in-crease in the average length of school
for one-year household members, the chances of poor
households being 0.293816 households with the
average length of school for smaller household
members. The marginal effect of this variable
indicates that the probability of households falling
into the poor category in the year is reduced by 2.23
ICEEE 2017 - 2nd International Conference on Economic Education and Entrepreneurship
728
percent if there is an additional one-year-old school
member household. From the interpretation of this
logit model proves that education as an effort to
improve human re-sources has a strong relationship
with the risk of households entering the poor
category. Poverty has a strong relationship with
education and economic growth. Education is a
multidimensional process that will impact on
economic growth and, on the other hand, reduce
poverty by increasing labour productivity (Brück,
n.d.) et.al. (2013). A more pro-active individual with
higher quality output results can earn higher wages.
Education plays a very important role in building
human capabilities and promoting economic growth
through skills and knowledge. The results of the study
(Brück, nd, et.al (2007: 26) also state that education
of members of households is important in improving
welfare.Babatunde & Adefabi (2005) argue that
education triggers economic growth through many
factors such as increased employment, Reducing
fertility and poverty levels, promoting technological
development, and the source of political stability
Education is the first step in the path of the
development process and providing the basis for
improving the socio-economic conditions of a
country education is considered an important
instrument for reducing poverty (Jung & Thorbecke,
2003).
The number of household members has a positive
and significant effect on the poverty status of the
household. Each additional one household member,
the chances of a household going into the poor
category would be 15558 households with fewer
household members. The greater the number of
household members the more likely the households
will be in the poor category. The marginal effect of
0.0335 means that if the mean sample of household
member’s increased one person, then the chances of
households entering the poor category will increase
by 3.35 percent. The results of this study indicate that
the number of household members has a positive and
significant effect on poverty, so that by the re-search
hypothesis and theory. Geda, et.al (2005) in the study
of the determinants of poverty in Kenya al-so stated
that household size has a positive influence and an
important determinant of poverty. A large number of
household members will reduce the ability of
households to meet the need to obtain knowledge
stock through educational investment.
The coefficient of age variable of the head of
household is equal to -0,006894 with odds ratio equal
to 0.9931. Artiga every increase of 1-year-old head of
household then the probability of the household into
the poor category will be 0.99 times household with
age of head of household is younger. The
interpretation of this result is that the older the head
of household, the lower the household risk of the poor
category. The marginal effect of -0.0005, means that
the increase of the sample means the age of head of
household by one year, then the probability of house-
holds entering the poor category will decrease by 0,05
percent. The older age of household head of
household income and household wealth is higher so
that it can support sufficiently expenditure to fulfil
education investment requirement. This result is no
different from the research conducted by Christiaen-
sen and Todo, 2014 in a study of the determinants of
poverty in developing countries found that the age of
household heads has a negative and significant effect
on poverty.
The work has a high correlation to household
poverty in Yogyakarta Special Province in 2013. The
estimated coefficient of the household head variable
is 0.753755 with an odds ratio of 2.1250. This means
that households with heads of households working in
agriculture have a probability of falling into the poor
category of 2.1250 times households with heads of
households working in non-agricultural sectors. In
other words, households with heads of households
working in the agricultural sector are more at risk of
poverty than households with heads of households
working in non-agricultural sectors. The marginal
effect of household head's job variable in the
agricultural sector in 2013 is 0,0571. This means that
if the opportunity to enter into the poor category will
in-crease by 5.71 percent if the head of households
works in the agricultural sector. Households working
in the agricultural sector have low productivity aver-
ages so that households with heads of households
working in the agricultural sector have a greater
likelihood of being poor. These results are consistent
with the results of the research from Kabananukye,
et.al (2004: 36) and (Geda, de Jong, Kimenyi, &
Mwabu, 2005) which suggest that the agricultural
sector positively affects poverty and is a strong
determinant of poverty reduction.
In addition to the head of the household business
field, in this study also included the variable status of
the work of the head of the household. The estimation
result of 2013 logit model obtained the estimated
value of the coefficient of the employment status of
head of household (SKR) equal to 0,532260 with ratio
odd ratio 1,7028. This means that house-holds with
heads of households working in the in-formal sector
have a probability of falling into the poor category
1.7028 times households with heads of households
working in the informal sector. Marginal effect
variable occupation status of head of house-hold in
the informal sector in 2013 is equal to 0.0403. This
means the opportunity to enter into the poor category
will increase by 4.03 percent if the head of household
works in the informal sector. Based on the data of
Susenas 2013, the characteristics of poor households
with informal employment are most of the heads of
Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory
729
households with the highest degrees of primary
school (71.56 percent), working in agriculture (64.65
percent) with unpaid employment assisted workers
(53.65 percent), 72 percent) and those with free
workers (24.88 percent). This suggests that poor
households working in the informal sector are more
than 70 percent educated with a low formal education
so that they will have limited skills and skills. They
mostly work on agricultural sectors that do not
require certain skills.
Other employment variables that can describe
the characteristics of poverty in D.I. Yogyakarta is the
average member of the working household (MPKR).
Based on the results of logit estimation, obtained the
estimated value of MPKR coefficient of -0.371064
with an odd ratio of 0.6900. This means that the
average number of household members working
increased 1, the probability that households will fall
into the poor category will be 0.6900 house-holds
with fewer household members working. This means
that the more stout the members of the house-hold are
working, the less likely the households will be poor.
The marginal effect of the MPKR variable is -0.0281,
which means that households will fall into the poor
category reduced by 2.81 percent if the number of
working households increases by one per-son.
Increasing the average number of working household
members will lower the likelihood of households
being categorised as poor.
The estimated value of the dummy of residence
(GEO3) is significant at the 5 percent significance
level with an estimated value of 0.404787, while the
odds ratio of 0.6671. This means that the probability
of households falling into the category of poor living
in the mainland area is 0.6671 times than in non-
mainland areas. These results indicate that non-land
areas have a higher poverty risk than inland areas.
The marginal effect of -0.0307. This means that
households in the poor category for households in the
mainland area will be reduced by 3.07 percent com-
pared with households living in non-mainland areas.
Characteristics of residence based on the location of
topography turned out to affect poverty. This is be-
cause the topography of the non-mainland area is
made up of slopes and valleys. This region is a
mountainous region so that transportation facilities
are still difficult, facilities and infrastructure that
support the fulfilment of household needs such as
education, health, economy or entertainment is still
very mini-mal. This result is not much different from
the results of the study of the determinants of poverty
in Kenya showing that poverty rates differ in different
regions (Kabananukye, et al., 2004).
4 CONCLUSIONS
The results of estimation and analysis, obtained some
conclusions as follows. Household size, age of head
of household, occupation of head of household,
employment status of head of household, occupation
of head of household, average of working member of
household, highest certificate owned by head of
household, average length of school of household
member And residential areas are the variables that
are able to explain the characteristics of poor
households in Special Province of Yogyakarta in
2013. Variables that can increase poverty by 2013
from the order of magnitude of marginal effect are:
employment in the agricultural sector, informal
employment status, and household size. Variables
that can reduce poverty by 2013 are the area of
mainland residence, the average member of the
working household, the average length of the
schooling of household members, the highest
certificate held by the head of the household and the
age of the head of the household. Increased
investment of human resources through formal
education can reduce the chances of poor households.
In contrast, agricultural employment, informal
employment status will increase the likelihood of
poor households.
REFERENCES
Afza, et al. 2013. Relationship among Education, Poverty
and Economic Growth in Pakistan: An Econometric
Analysis, Journal of Elementary Education Vol.22, No.
1 pp.23-45
Barnes, S., 2005. The Cost of being Poor: A Comparative
Study of Life in Poor Urban Neighbourhoods in Gary,
Indiana. State University of New York Press. Albany.
Bassetti, T., 2008. Economic Growth : Institutional and
Social Dynamics Education and Poverty in a Solow
Growth Model, (February).
Bassetti, T., 2012. Education as a social agreement. Journal
of Socio-Economics, 41(1), 817.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2011.10.005
Brück, T., n.d.. Determinants of Poverty During
Transition : Household Survey Evidence From
Ukraine, (December 2007), 140.
Christiaensen, L., Todo, Y., 2014. Poverty reduction during
the rural-urban transformation - The role of the missing
middle. World Development, 63, 4358.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.10.002
Geda, A., de Jong, N., Kimenyi, M. S., Mwabu, G., 2005.
Determinants of Poverty in Kenya : A Household Level
Analysis. Economic Working Papers - Digital
Commons, (August). https://doi.org/ISSN 0921-0210
Grimm, M., 2005. Educational policies and poverty
reduction in C??te d’Ivoire. Journal of Policy
ICEEE 2017 - 2nd International Conference on Economic Education and Entrepreneurship
730
Modeling, 27(2), 231247.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2004.12.002
Guillaumont, P., Guillaumont Jeanneney, S., Wagner, L.,
2017. How to Take into Account Vulnerability in Aid
Allocation Criteria and Lack of Human Capital as Well:
Improving the Performance Based Allocation. World
Development, 90, 2740.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.10.045
Jones, B. F., 2014. The Human Capital Stock : A
Generalised Approach. American Economic Review,
104(11), 375277. https://doi.org/10.3386/w17487
Jones, C., 1998. Introduction to Economic Growth.
Jones, C. I., 2001. Human Capital, Ideas, and Economic
Growth. Investigaciones Economicas, 25(3), 129.
Jung, H. S., Thorbecke, E., 2003. The impact of public
education expenditure on human capital, growth, and
poverty in Tanzania and Zambia: A general equilibrium
approach. Journal of Policy Modeling, 25(8), 701725.
Kabananukye, Kaban I.B., Andrine E.K. Kabananukye, J.
Krishnamurty, Daisy Owamugasho. 2004. Economic
Growth, Employment, Poverty and Pro-Poor Policies in
Uganda, Recovery and Reconstruction Departement,
International Labour Office, Geneva. 32-57
Romer, P. M., 1986. Increasing Returns and Long-Run
Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002
1037.
Education and Poverty in Special Province of Yogyakarta: The Approach of Solow Growth Technology Model in Production Theory
731