Power System Optimization Problems: Game Theory Applications
Sudha Balagopalan and Ravishankar S.
Vidya Academy of Science and Technology, APJ Abdul Kalam Technological University, Thrissur, India
Keywords: Game Theory, Power System Optimization, Pricing, Graph Theory, Resource Allocation.
Abstract: We look at the conflict situation in power system problems from an optimization perspective and use Game
Theory (GT) concepts for modelling and solving the problem. In order to model the conflicts effectively, we
first identify the players, the optimizing quantity and the optimizing platform. This paper details two power
system problems and present a case study. We also identify two more areas where the same principles may
be applied. Though our work focuses on Cooperative Game Theory (CGT), an extension to the Non-
Cooperative Game Theory (NGT) platform is possible. Since GT is more relevant to a market structure, we
use market engineering principles including multilateral trades, differential pricing, inverse elasticity rule,
graph theoretical allocation, etc. as tools for organizing the optimization process. A useful addition for
inducing stability in the decision making process is the concept of ‘Power Vectors’ borrowed from sports and
game parlance for ceding players. Results are encouraging, with a transmission loss reduction of more than
70% in a five bus and 40% in a 24 bus system. We conclude that both versions of GT, the CGT and NGT are
powerful tools for optimization in a practical scenario with conflicts and contradictory incentives.
1 INTRODUCTION
Many power system problems are conflict ridden
requiring application of Game Theory (GT) concepts
to mathematically model the complexities and
optimize the ‘live’ variables. Conflict situations
warrant the need to compete or cooperate/ negotiate
and accordingly choose strategies to maximize
benefits via a rational decision making. In GT, the
decision variables contributing to the benefits are
‘live’ and evolve continuously based on strategies.
This decision evolution procedure in a Cooperative
Game Theory (CGT) model uses coalitions of players
to maximize social welfare. Coalitions to reap more
gains and share benefits are outcomes of shared
information. However striking a discord and falling
out of coalitions before the grand coalition is formed
is a disruptive eventuality to be addressed in such
scenarios. If decision making is simultaneous,
without sharing of information, the operational
structure is non-cooperative (NGT) and the force-
majeure is the competition embedded in the game.
A distinctive feature of CGT is the ‘characteristic
function’ which is maximized via formation of
coalitions. Since the objective is conflict resolution,
all perceived road-blocks or desirables may be used
to embellish the characteristic function. Moreover,
the strategies focus on maintenance of accord among
coalition partners via an acceptable pay-off or sharing
of benefits. This is to prevent the partners leaving the
coalition for greener pastures at any point of time.
Similarly for pay-offs in NGT, the strategies opted by
the players are with the objective of achieving
equilibrium, also called the Nash equilibrium. This is
a ‘minimax’ solution, since each player minimizes the
maximum payoff possible for other players if the
game is zero-sum; they simultaneously minimize
their own maximum loss. Thus situations with many
complex options and each with several outcomes are
most suitable for GT based modelling. The
assumption and/or the hitch is that only rational
decisions are taken by the players and nothing is left
to chance.So, GT concepts can be applied to model
engineering problems with conflicts which can be
resolved by adopting strategies that optimize the
‘live’ design variables.
On examining reported works on applications of
GT concepts to power system problems, it is noted
problems in transmission expansion, loss allocation,
demand/ response management, pricing, smart grid
applications, renewable energy sizing, distribution
networks, etc. are prominent. (Sore et.al 2006, Zhu
et.al 2012, Kreyac et.al 2013, Mediwaththe, 2017,
Mekontso et.al, 2019, He et.al 2019, Chen et.al 2017,
Balagopalan, S. and S., R.
Power System Optimization Problems: Game Theory Applications.
DOI: 10.5220/0009170302550262
In Proceedings of the 9th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems (ICORES 2020), pages 255-262
ISBN: 978-989-758-396-4; ISSN: 2184-4372
Copyright
c
2022 by SCITEPRESS Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
255
Keren 2017, Contreras 1997) In all cases, two
influencing factors observed are: Elasticity of
demand versus price and incentive based commerce.
Both factors make GT option possible in complex
power system parlance. Elasticity is proposed to be
designed and injected into the 4 problems presented
here. And a differential pricing structure for power
system variables like energy, demand blocks, open
access of transmission corridors, etc is adopted to
stimulate the incentive/ disincentive ridden
commerce. Thus the four problems are appropriately
modified and attendant issues addressed as follows.
2 GAME THEORY IN POWER
SYSTEM OPTIMIZATION
Some pertinent questions on GT based optimization
are raised here to define the power system problems
presented, model them and identify the appropriate
solution approaches. The conflicts associated with
specific problems give the impetus for the approach.
How can the conflicts be represented to apply GT
concepts to arrive at workable solutions?
How do the conflicts suggest theplayers?
What would be the decision/ design variables and
how do they evolve and stages thereof?
What are the strategies that influence the
evolution of the best of solutions?
What is the level of information availability and
sharing, for designing strategy sets?
How is the characteristic function formulated?
What is the outcomeof sharing the benefits?
Optimum power flow in corridors and allocation
of transmission price are modelled here. Two recent
reported works, power system islanding and then
restoration, both with conflicting requirements, are
presented as amenable to GT applied model with
evolved solutions based on incentives and
disincentives. The conflict modelling, both in the
CGT and NGT platforms, are projected here.
2.1 Optimizing Power Flow in the
Power Corridors
Some conflicts to be resolved in restructured power
markets requiring modelling via GT concepts follow
1. Due to uneven generation and usage pattern in
grids, quantum of power moved over transmission
lines is large. In some corridors power shuttling is of
the order of 3-5 times the total transactions, causing
unacceptable congestion, voltage drops and power
losses in lines unless optimal transactions are made.
2. An otherwise useful Optimal Power Flow (OPF)
analysis tool has little significance in an electricity
market which has distributed and closely guarded
information. Also,OPF focuses on influence of
generators on energy prices to derive line impacts.
These impacts as feedback inputs cannot target
control of abuse of the power lines. This is especially
true due to distributed ownership of generation and
transmission assets and their conflicting incentives in
an electricity market.
3. In an electricity market, generating companies
(GENCOS) do not reveal sales data and capture
maximum power portfolios resorting to even profit
cuts from energy prices. Then more distribution
companies (DISCOS) buy cheaper energy leading to
congestion and other problems on the network; thus
the end users make profits while the afflicted party,
i.e. the Transmission Provider (TP) provides access
for both use and abuse of the network.
4. However, power flows obey Kirchhoff’s laws
only and no contractual laws. While in the erstwhile
system, roles and responsibilities and a centralized
authority were assigned, an electricity market is ‘free-
for-all. Then TP is the only entity who can exercise
control on the ‘runaway’ on lines. Then TP should
optimize trades of the GENCOs and conduct least
loss iteration. However, too many rules of the road
like curtailment, loading vector etc. cannot be laid
down by the TP since competition is hampered, the
reason for the development of electricity markets.
Thus, though optimization has applicability as a tool,
the implementation of its findings needs other market
engineering tools as in GT concepts.
2.1.1 GT Modelling of Power Transactions
Some choices are made to model the problem in the
GT platform. (Varaiya 1997, Sudha 2011)
1. A multilateral market structure is chosen over the
pool. Thus a cartel, prone to dangerous power and
market games and commercial considerations
outweighing engineering requirements is averted.
Since no reliable cost-benefit data is revealed by the
market agents a transaction model independent of the
economic data of the end-users is the best.
2. The distinctive entities are thus the GENCOs,
DISCOs and the central TP. The GENCOs have
influence over determining the Energy Charges (EC).
The TP is given the prerogative over the construct of
the Transmission Service Charge (TSC). Finally the
choice of determining who to buy from and in what
ratio will lie with the DISCOs.
3. To implement least loss formulation, an appeal to
the selfish profit motive of the end-users is the game
ICORES 2020 - 9th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
256
plan. This encompasses them in a game to collude or
cooperate so as to minimize the impact on the grid. In
cooperative games, modus operandi includes both
collusion and cooperation and so is inferred as the
best choice. This is because collusion is not
detrimental to the ultimate aim of least loss and other
impacts on lines as evinced by the TP, but serves only
to increase the cohesion between the cooperating
agents. Another reason for choosing CGT is that GT
is one of the strongest tools of market engineering, of
which CGT uses both the nuances of coalition- threat
(when with others) and promises (when with oneself),
leading to more stable coalitions. If maximum
benefits are given to the grand coalition, when all
loads are transacted, then the combinatorial process
of coalition formation is faster and this thought
process is employed.
4. DISCOs play the game because they can form best
coalitions, being privy to all local information. This
helps to identify partners causing counter-flows and
yet enhance their trades in a multilateral set-up.
5. Four phases of CGT are viewed here in a
multilateral trade structure. 1. DISCOs derive Local
information and based on merits become decision
authorities. 2. TP computes and broadcasts Central
information vital for the next phase using the
communicated trades. 3. In the Common Information
Derivation and Negotiation phase DISCOs divulge
information conducive to trades with some trades
dropped, some increased, exchanged or even shared
for individual, coalitional and group benefits. In this
manner a set of stable coalitions or the grand coalition
are formed in Phase 4 and the result is committed and
accordingly scheduled.
The TSC is next designed as the characteristic
function, which dictates decisions and negotiations.
2.1.2 TSC - Characteristic Function
The design of the TSC answers three questions:
1. What is the benefit of cooperating in coalitions?
2. In an asymmetric environment how do the agents
locate reliable / fruitful partnerships?
3. How can agents ascertain that what is bought is
what is got since electricity is fungible?
TSC is designed (Sudha 2011) considering some
entity interactions andbenefits of co-operating and
honouring transactionsas the characteristic function.
a. Instead of passively providing open access, the TP
manipulates the situation such that each DISCO is
forced to compare TSC with EC and arrive at a
compromise solution. The design should penalize all
unacceptable transactions and be the lowest for a least
loss formulation for a set of loads at any time.
b. Since the DISCOS and GENCOs have
contradictory intentions and strategies only DISCOs
are chosen to play. On comparing EC and TSC, the
DISCOs shift their contracts to more profitable
GENCOs. Since GENCOs do not control both EC and
TSC, market is not skewed. DISCOs are accountable
for the loss and play to reduce it.
c. Market engineering principles are beacons in the
design of prices since perception exists that electricity
sector has little elasticity. Experimenting with
differential pricing and penalized deviations from
least loss condition, elasticity of transmission and an
empowered design of TSC was achieved.
The features in the TSC enable the DISCOS and
their coalitions to identify scope for partnerships with
an understanding on how to share the TSC. In an
information asymmetric market only a few sources
are reliable. Therefore the concept of power vectors
from graph theory has been developed and put to use
in three phases of the game. The main idea of power
vector is that a node derives maximum power from
subservient nodes and their chain of successors.
Using power vectors, if DISCO A say appraises
DISCO B as having a high strength it means that B
makes a good candidate for causing counter-flows in
relevant lines via B’s trades. Also, the benefits for
agent A continue to increase if B’s trades enhance
further. But the appreciation needs to be mutual for
any meaningful dialogues between the two agents in
the common information phase.
In short the players of the CGT based game are
DISCOs; the design variables are the trades with
minimized TSC. Strategies of DISCOs identify
suitable coalitions causing counter-flows in lines.
Information asymmetry is resolved through coalition
derived information. Stability for the solution is
ensured via power vector governed pay-off design.
The TSC, as the bone of contention gives the design
of payoff vector for forming coalitions. If feasible, it
must lie in the solution space of the game.
2.2 TSC Sharing Problem
To match power allocated by GENCOs with trade
contracts, fungible nature of electricity is a deterrent.
In a trade based market, it is distressing that after all
the haggling and negotiations between DISCOs and
GENCOs, power flow from a specific generator to a
precise load is affected by other trades on the grid,
even gaming. In short in an electricity market with an
assembly of trades, what is bought is not what is got;
negotiation entered into by the agents is based on
pseudo- trades. Since all trades mix on the grid
system, contracts exist even if there is nil or minimal
Power System Optimization Problems: Game Theory Applications
257
allocation from a generator and impact on the lines
still have to be accounted for. Game and Graph theory
are used to resolve such ambiguities.
2.2.1 CGT and Transmission Pricing
CGT comes hand in phase3; when two DISCOs or a
conglomerate consider further mergers, after
resolution using graph theoretical allocation. The
resource allotment enables the partners to negotiate
further, contract more profitable trades at lower grid
impact and by cooperating, a lower TSC. Moreover,
divergence from a common understanding is tackled
using Ramsey pricing rule. Thus, via best trades at
every coalitional step, the grand coalition is reached.
Diametrically opposite to the existing power
system, the chain of events in the electricity markets
leading to power flow starts from the other end of the
spectrum i.e. trades are contracted and thereafter there
is a confluence of trades on the transmission lines. So,
first demand and supply is visualized as a set of
trades, then assembled via a combinatorial process.
Trades merge with an eye on TSC, two at a time in
the first iteration, all the time going for the least loss
trades. In subsequent iterations the fused trades
continue to coalesce till the grand coalition or a set of
stable coalitions is reached. The attainment of the
solution, i.e. the payoff vector is the proof of the
feasibility of the proposed model. Of the several
techniques, the marginal vector, if it can be obtained
is the stable and unique solution and is strived for.
2.2.2 Stable Coalition for Sharing TSC
1. The construct of TSC and the elastic curves lend
convexity and superadditivity (Herings et.al 2006,
2007) to the game, resulting in an economically
feasible payoff vector existing in the solution space.
Convexity implies that more benefits accrue as more
agents join the coalition. Hence, the TP reveals the
maximum benefit only, which a grand coalition alone
can earn. At intermediate steps the perceived
minimum of TSC is used for evaluating the coalitions.
ThusTP dispatches all loads or assembles all the best
trades contracted i.e. schedule generators to meet all
loads and losses.
2. Permutational convexity in a game implies
incentives for including more, higher ranked players
in the coalitions for a specific ranked permutation.
Also with a permutationally consistent power vector
(rank order echoes the power vector) the socially
stable solution core has the marginal vector, a highly
desirable unique payoff vector or solution. Social,
technical, commercial, considerations can rank the
players and a combination of these is proposed as a
power vector, also for checking consistency.
3. A permutationally convex game is designed with
a compatible power vector to ensure the presence of
the sole marginal vector in the socially stable core.
(Permutational compatibility ensures that no agent
can hijack the game in her favour.) The locally
computable power vectors and the derivation of
hierarchy proposed are workable and compatible with
all the steps taken so far and hence the solution is
rationally true and acceptable.
4. Certainly, though not unique, a valid solution
space is realized. It was checked for balancedness
using power vectors of coalitions that sustain these
payoff vectors. All these steps assure a socially stable
core which is needed for stability an absolute
necessity to prevent anarchy on the network.
2.2.3 TSC and Power Vectors
For a network with n nodes, L lines, line flow z, and
line loss q, if weights for penalizing loss, sum of
power flowing in all lines and flow in congested lines
are a ($/MW
2
h), b and d ($/MWh) respectively and
embedded cost is cin ($/hr.), then the price function
p(q)in $/hr is

+b

+c
(1)
To measure power of players (Herings et.al 2001)
ascribe to a node, power, from both the number as
also power of its successor. Let
be the collection of
irreflexive digraphs on the vertex set
{1, 2 , , }Nn
with (, )ij N N
denoting the arc
ij
, ((i,j) є A
(node i dominates j). The positional power function is
the function
:
p
n
f
R which maps each
A
to
1
11
() ( )
p
AA
f
AITs
nn

(2)
Here
A
T
is the adjacency matrix of
A
, with the
th
ij entry
1
A
ij
t
if (, )ij is an arc of
A
and
0
otherwise;
A
s
is the score vector giving the number of
successors of each node. The TSC is used as the
characteristic function and power vectors are used to
form coalitions and also to design the socially stable
core as shown in the case study in section 3.
2.3 Islanding of a Power System
The problem of optimized islanding of power system
using GT concepts, on fault clearance is briefed.
1. The conflicts to be addressed are: number and
extent of islands, coherency of generators within, and
the power corridors to be evacuated, priority of loads.
ICORES 2020 - 9th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
258
2. The players are the GENCOs (of islands based on
geographical proximity/ parts thereof).
3. The characteristic function is to be derived as a
quadratic, penalizing the most unwanted outcomes of
islanding such that an elastic curve can be derived.
4. The phases of coalition formation based on a
power vector design which shows the technical
features of the consequence of islanding.
5. The solution with pay-off vectors.
Depending on the catastrophic event preceding it,
the restoration process also is to be optimized.
Figure 1: A 5 bus system.
2.3 Power System Restoration
1. All agents will seek priority in getting the power
restored, because of the enormous economic and
social implications with aligned conflicts.
2. The islanded areas and some privileged loads will
be the players of this optimization game.
3. To use NGT and arrive at a Nash equilibrium.
4. The solution is to be iteratively inducted with the
outcome of optimal restoration vector as pay-off.
3 A CASE STUDY
A case study for a 5 bus system for the first two
problems in optimization is given below. Briefly the
following phases are explained:
1. A set of .multilateral trades are derived from the
problem using graph theoretical allocation (Table 1)
(Wu, 2000, Varaiya, 1999, Penh et.al 2002).
2. Next is the local phase computations and
derivation of all required information by all DISCOs.
(Sample cases of 2 DISCOs deriving power vectors
for their own trades and other useful data for
negotiations are given in Table 2, 4).
3. The coalition move in the direction of data related
to optimal trades using power vectors (Table 2, 3, 4,).
4. Optimal trades are derived & scheduled and
committed at the best total TSC (Table 4).
5. Sharing of the benefits in the final phase, which
proves the feasibility of the method and is reflected in
the final core is derived. (Fig. 3). (Appendix).
Table 1: Division of power demand and flows into trades.
Disco on buses Genco on bus 1 Genco on bus 2
No: (Demand) Load (MW) Load (MW)
2 (20MW) 13.623 6.376
3 (45MW) 39.544 5.456
4 (40MW) 30.463 9.536
5 (60MW) 41.374 18.628
Total load 129.74 40
Line loss 4.77MW
Sum of power flow i
n
all lines
262.6 MW
Table 2: Local Information computation: Power Vectors.
Disco2 buying 20MW from
Genco1
Disco3 buying 45MW
from Genco4
Bus No:
Lines with
t
i
j
=1
s
A
Power
vector
Lines
with t
i
j
=1
s
A
Power
vector
Ref 0-1 1 .2401 0-4 1 .2736
1 12,1-3 2 .4402 1-3 1 .2021
2 2-0 1 .2067 1-3,2-3 2 .4024
3 2-3,3-4 2 .4347 3-0 1 .2123
4 2-4,4-5 2 .4013 From 4 3 .6414
5 2-5 1 .2012 2-5 1 .2338
Table 3: Coalition Formation using Common Information.
Bus
Power
Vector
Graph theoretical allocation of load
Ref 0.5187 Load Gen. 1 Gen. 4
coalitio
n {2,3}
1 0.4528 20MW 13.322 6.678MW
2 0.4620 45MW 5.886MW 39.11MW
3 0.2532 40MW 0 40MW
4 0.6598 Loss .231MW -
5 0.2437 Total 19.439 85.798
Table 4: Optimal trades as derived in the Central
Information Derivation Phase.
Optimal Trades in MW
bus(demand) Load- Genco 1 Load- Genco 4
2(20) 13.846 6.154
3 (45) 5.002 39.996
4 (40) 0 40
5 (60) 23.654 36.546
Total 44.102 122.696
Loss 1.6 MW
Sum of power flow in all lines: 163.7 MW
4 CONCLUSIONS
It is mooted that game theory offers a very suitable
platform to model complex situations in power
system optimization problems. The whole idea of GT
Power System Optimization Problems: Game Theory Applications
259
concepts encourages choices and hence is fertile
ground for having different perspectives for deciding
the players of the game. The benefits nor its
maximization process is narrow framed and offers
plenty of research opportunities. The three phases of
CGT was demonstrated to successfully coordinate
multilateral trades using two tools, a suitable TSC and
power vector and that the Socially Stable game is
instrumental in ensuring stable trades. The case
studies on 5 bus and 24 bus (not shown here) power
systems reveal the following advantages.
1. In a 5 bus, 169.74 MW demand system with a loss
of 4.44 MW and a total power shuttling over the lines
of 262.6 MW is optimized to a power system with 1.6
MW loss and a total power of 163.7 MW shuttling on
the lines.
2. A 24 bus system with a demand of 1219 MW, and
36.355 MW loss optimizes to 15.43 MW loss and
power shuttling dropping from 3825 to 2805 MW via
GT concepts.
All contributions to the process are based on
market engineering techniques which are more
applicable, suitable and acceptable.
In Figure 2 is given one such contribution where
a coalition based optimization is visualized as a step
in the negotiation phase.
Figure 2: Least loss iteration by coalition {2,3}.
Another contribution is indicated in Figure 4
where a sample of a TSC designed in a novel manner
such that the elastic nature is utilized by the DISCOs
for least loss iteration.
The derivation and adaptation of such vectors at
each stage of the GT based optimization is another
contribution, especially since it has been imported
from the sports and games field to cede players. Here,
the powerful use is for deciding by the agents,
initiating the trades, the best partner to obtain counter-
flows and thus reduce TSC as the partnership deal
between the coalition partners.
The inherent choice factor, its capacity to promote
competition and scope for negotiation and extraction
of hidden information, resolve the uncertainty factor
in an information asymmetric complex scenario. In
conclusion it can be said that the biggest engineering
advantage of GT is that solution of the problem
becomes a common agenda and a unifying force, even
in a profit motivated milieu, where commercial
considerations overrule engineering requirements.
REFERENCES
F. Sore, H. Rudnick, J. Zolezzi, ,IEEE Transactions on
Power Systems, 2006Definition of an efficient
Transmission System using Cooperative Game Theory.
Fayçal, Elatrech Kratima, Fatima Zohra Gherbi Fatiha
Lakdja. In Issue 23, 2013 LEONARDO JOURNAL OF
SCIENCES, Applications of Cooperative Game Theory
in Power System Allocation Problems.
C. Mekontso, A. Abdulkarim, I. S. Madugu, O. Ibrahim, Y.
A. Adediran, 2019, Computer Engineering and
Applications Vol. 8, No. 1 ,Review of Optimization
Techniques for Sizing Renewable EnergySystems,
Quanyan Zhu, Jiangmeng Zhang, Peter W. Sauer,
Alejandro Dom´ınguez-Garc´ıa, Tamer Basar, 2012, In
IEEEXplore proceedings of American Control
Conference, A Game-Theoretic Framework for Control
of Distributed Renewable-Based Energy Resources in
Smart Grids
Juntao Chen, Quanyan Zhu, 2017, In Vol. 8 of IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid A Game-Theoretic
Framework for Resilient and Distributed Generation
Control of Renewable Energies in Microgrids,
Min-fan He, Fu-xing Zhang, Yong, Jian Chen, Jue Wang,
Rui Wang, 2019, Energies, A Distributed Demand Side
Energy Management Algorithm for Smart Grid
P. Varaiya, F. Wu, IEEE Trans. On EP& ES, 1999 Vol.21
Coordinated Multilateral Trades for Electric Power
Networks: Theory and Implementation
Keren Chen, Fushuan Wen, Chung-Li Tseng , Minghui
Chen, Zeng Yang, Hongwei Zhao, Huiyu Shang,2019,
Energies, A Game Theory-Based Approach for
Vulnerability Analysis of a Cyber-Physical Power
System
F. F. Wu, Y. Nei, P. Wei, IEEE Trans on P S 2000 Power
Transfer Allocation for Open Access Using Graph
Theory - Fundamentals and Applications in Systems
without Loop-flow
J. C. Penh, H. Jiang, IEEE Proceedings on Generation,
Transmission and Distribution, 2002Contributions of
individual generators to complex power losses and
flows- Part1: Fundamental theory
J. C. Penh, H. Jiang, IEEE Proceedings on Generation,
Transmission and Distribution, 2002, Contributions of
individual generators to complex power losses and
flows- Part2: Algorithm and Simulation
P. J. J. Herings, G. van der Laan, D. Talman, Social Choice
and Welfare, 2001Measuring the power of Nodes in
Digraphs
ICORES 2020 - 9th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
260
P. J. J. Herings, G. van der Laan, D. Talman, Games and
Economic Behavior, Volume 59, 2007, The socially
stable core in structured transferable utility games
J. J. Herings, G. van der Laan, D. Talman, Springer 2006,
Theory and Decision 62, The socially structured games
Mediwaththe Gedara Chathurika, 2017, Game-theoretic
Methods for Small-scale Demand-sideManagement in
Smart Grid, PhD Thesis, UNSW, Australia
J. Contreras, F. F. Wu, 1997A Cooperative Game Theory
Approach to Transmission Planning in Power Systems,
Ph.D. dissertation, Dept. of EE and CS, University of
California, Berkeley
Sudha Balagopalan, 2011, Development of An Integrated
Model for Transmission Sector in Electricity Markets,
National Institute of Technology, Calicut
APPENDIX
Figure 3: Socially Stable Core for a 5 bus TSC sharing
game.
Table 5: Optimizing trades derived in, local and negotiation & common Information Derivation Phase.
Buyer
Disco
Seller Genco Power Trade in MWline loss z or ƒ
L
Z or ƒ
L
in 1-3 Z or ƒ
L
in 4-5
2 1 20 .0674 25.43 3.143 .5714
2 4 20 .0869 36.19 3.429 3.619
3 1 45 .6017 93.86. 16.71 5.143
3 4 45 .1794 53.79 1.929 1.714
5 1 60 1.571 139.9 12.86 18.1
5 4 60 1.307 117.9 6.857 27.24
{2,3} 1 65 .8954 108.4 19.86 4.571
{2,3} 1,4 (20,45) .2314 69.07 5.072 2.286
{2,3) 4 65 .4417 82.81 13.29 1.524
(2,3} 4,1 (20,45) .3485 85.83 1.5 5.333
{2,3}- (G1-13.32& 5.89 to 2&3),
(G4-6.68 & 39.11 to 2&3)
.2312 69.02 4.812 2.406
{2,5} 1 80 2.016 158.7 16 18.67
{2,5} 1,4 (20,60) 1.43 132.5 3.714 27.89
{2,5} 4 80 1.567 132.9 9.429 21.71
{2,5} 4,1 (20,60) 1.742 146.9 10.29 30.86
{2,5}- (G1-12.73&21.91 to 2&5)
(G4-7.27 & 38.09 to 2 & 5)
1.3622 124.1 1.095 25.58
{3,5} 1 105 3.099 194.5 29.57 12.95
{3,5} 4,1 (45,60) 1.622 150.6 14.79 19.81
{3,5} 1,4 (45,60) 1.415 145.3 9.857 22.1
{3,5} 4 105 1.651 154.1 4.929 28.95
{3,5}-(G1-5 & 25.76 to 2 & 5 ) (G4-40 & 34.24 to 2
&5 )
1.3512 141.3 5.177 24.27
{2,3,5}-(G1-13.85,5,23.45 to 2,3&5 ) (G4-
6.15,40,36.55 to 2,3&5)
1.604 163.7 5.607 26.1
Power System Optimization Problems: Game Theory Applications
261
Figure 4: Elasticity curve- Demand Vs TSC for 165MW met by generation at bus 1&2.
ICORES 2020 - 9th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
262