Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by
Means of Symmetric Solutions
Jos
´
e Miguel Gim
´
enez
Department of Mathematics, Technical University of Catalonia, Avda. Bases de Manresa 61, E-08242 Manresa, Spain
Keywords:
Cooperative game, Coalition structure, Marginal contribution, Semivalue, Separability.
Abstract:
We say that two situations described by cooperative games are inseparable by a family of solutions, when they
obtain the same allocation by all solution concept of this family. The situation of separability by a family of
linear solutions reduces to separability from the null game. This is the case of the family of solutions based
on marginal contributions weighted by coefficients only dependent of the coalition size: the semivalues. It is
known that for games with four or more players, the spaces of inseparable games from the null game contain
games different to zero-game. We will prove that for five or more players, when a priori coalition blocks are
introduced in the situation described by the game, the dimension of the vector spaces of inseparable games
from the null game decreases in an important manner.
1 INTRODUCTION
Probabilistic values as a solution concept for coop-
erative games were introduced in (Weber, 1988). The
payoff that a probabilistic value assigns to each player
is a weighted sum of its marginal contributions to the
coalitions, where the weighting coefficients form a
probabilistic distribution over the coalitions to which
it belongs. A particular type of probabilistic values is
formed by the semivalues that were defined in (Dubey
et al., 1981). In this case the weighting coefficients
are independent of the players and they only depend
on the coalition size. Semivalues represent a natu-
ral generalization of both the Shapley value (Shapley,
1953) and the Banzhaf value (Banzhaf, 1965; Owen,
1975). According to this approach, many works deal
with the semivalues, with general properties as in
(Carreras and Gim
´
enez, 2011), or applied to simple
games as in (Carreras et al., 2003), and many others.
It is possible to find two cooperative games that
obtain the same payoff vector for each semivalue. We
say that these games are inseparable by semivalues.
By the linearity property of semivalues, we can re-
duce the problem of separability between games to
separability from the null game. The vector subspace
of inseparable games from the null game by semival-
ues is called in (Amer et al., 2003) shared kernel and
its dimension is 2
n
n
2
+ n 2, where n denotes the
number of players. For spaces of cooperative games
with four or more players, the shared kernel contains
games different to zero-game
The semivalues form an important family of solu-
tions. We can evaluate their amplitude according to
their faculty to separate games. Two games are sepa-
rable if their difference does not belong to the shared
kernel. The dimension of this subspace would mark
the separation impossibility. In this paper we consider
coalition structures in the player set. It is not diffi-
cult to find in the literature many papers devoted to
the modified semivalues by coalition structures, for
instance (Albizuri, 2009) or (Gim
´
enez and Puente,
2015), among others. Our purpose is to reduce the di-
mension of the vector subspace of inseparable games
from the null game. For cooperative games with five
or more players, modified semivalues for games with
coalition structure (Amer and Gim
´
enez, 2003) are
able to reduce in a significant way the dimension of
the shared kernel.
In addition, once an a-priori ordering is chosen in
the player set, we can see in (Amer et al., 2003) that
the shared kernel is spanned by specific {−1, 0,1}-
valued games. These games are known as commuta-
tion games. Now, we will prove that the vector sub-
space of inseparable games from the null game by
modified semivalues is spanned by games introduced
here with the name of expanded commutation games.
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2
we remember the solution concepts of semivalue and
semivalue modified for games with a coalition struc-
ture whose allocations can be computed by means of
242
GimÃl’nez J.
Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by Means of Symmetric Solutions.
DOI: 10.5220/0006116802420249
In Proceedings of the 6th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems (ICORES 2017), pages 242-249
ISBN: 978-989-758-218-9
Copyright
c
2017 by SCITEPRESS Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
the multilinear extension (Owen, 1972) of each game.
Also, nomenclature and main results for inseparable
games by semivalues are described. Section 3 shows
that commutation games that are the solution for the
problem of separability by semivalues does not have
in general the same properties with respect to separa-
bility by modified semivalues. In section 4 two suffi-
cient conditions for separability by modified semival-
ues are proposed. Finally, in Section 5 we determine
the dimension and a basis of the vector subspace of
inseparable games from the null game by modified
semivalues.
2 PRELIMINARIES
2.1 Cooperative Games and Semivalues
A cooperative game with transferable utility is a pair
(N,v), where N is a finite set of players and v : 2
N
R is the so-called characteristic function, which as-
signs to every coalition S N a real number v(S), the
worth of coalition S, and satisfies the natural condi-
tion v(
/
0) = 0. With G
N
we denote the set of all co-
operative games on N. For a given set of players N,
we identify each game (N,v) with its characteristic
function v.
The multilinear extension MLE (Owen, 1972) of
cooperative game v G
N
is a function f
v
: [0,1]
N
R
defined as
f
v
(x
1
,x
2
,..., x
n
) =
SN
iS
x
i
j /S
(1 x
j
)v(S), (1)
so that it provides all information of the game con-
tained in its characteristic function v.
A function ψ : G
N
R
N
is called a solution and
it represents a method to measure the negotiation
strength of the players in the game. The payoff vec-
tor space R
N
is also called the allocation space. The
semivalues (Dubey et al., 1981) as solution concept
were introduced and axiomatically characterized by
Dubey, Neyman and Weber in 1981. The payoff to
the players for a game v G
N
by a semivalue ψ is an
average of marginal contributions of each player:
ψ
i
[v] =
S3i
p
s
[v(S) v(S\{i})] i N, (2)
where the weighting coefficients p
s
only depend on
the coalition size and verify
n
s=1
n1
s1
p
s
= 1 and
p
s
0 for 1 s n. With Sem(G
N
) we denote the
set of all semivalues on G
N
.
Given a number α R, 0 < α < 1, we call bi-
nomial semivalue ψ
α
to the semivalue whose coeffi-
cients are p
α,s
= α
s1
(1α)
ns
. The extreme cases
correspond to values α = 0 and α = 1. For α = 0
we obtain the dictatorial index ψ
0
, with coefficients
(1,0, ..., 0), whereas for α = 1 we obtain the marginal
index ψ
1
, with coefficients (0,..., 0, 1):
(ψ
0
)
i
[v] = v({i}) i N,
(ψ
1
)
i
[v] = v(N) v(N \ {i}) i N.
It is proven in (Amer and Gim
´
enez, 2003) that n
different binomial semivalues form a reference sys-
tem for the set of semivalues on G
N
. Given n dif-
ferent numbers α
j
in [0,1], for every semivalue ψ
Sem(G
N
) they exist unique coefficients λ
j
, 1 j n,
such that ψ =
n
j=1
λ
j
ψ
α
j
.
The Banzhaf value (Banzhaf, 1965; Owen, 1975)
is the binomial semivalue for α = 1/2. As it happens
for the Banzhaf value, we see in (Amer and Gim
´
enez,
2003) that the allocation by every binomial semivalue
can calculate replacing in the partial derivatives of
MLE the variables by value α:
(ψ
α
)
i
[v] =
f
v
x
i
(α) i N, where α = (α,...,α).
In addition, the allocation for every semivalue can
be computed by means of a product of two matrices,
ψ[v] = B Λ, (3)
where the matrix B depends on each reference system
of semivalues B = (b
i j
)
1i, jn
with b
i j
= (ψ
α
j
)
i
[v] =
f
v
x
i
(α
j
) and Λ is the column matrix of the coefficients
of ψ in this reference system, Λ
t
= (λ
1
λ
2
·· · λ
n
) if
ψ =
n
j=1
λ
j
ψ
α
j
. Thus, a (n×n)-matrix summarizes
the payments by any semivalue to all players of a
given game v.
2.2 Cooperative Games and Coalition
Structures
The formation of coalition blocks in the player set N
gives rise to the construction of modified solutions in
attention to this circumstance. It is the case of the
Owen coalition value (Owen, 1977) from the Shap-
ley value (Shapley, 1953) or the modified Banzhaf
value for games with coalition structure (Owen, 1981)
from the Banzhaf value. If we denote by B =
{B
1
,B
2
,..., B
m
} the coalition structure in N, in both
cases, the construction of the modified solutions fol-
lows a parallel way. It is considered a modified quo-
tient game for each coalition S B
j
and it is applied
the Shapley or Banzhaf value. This action defines a
game in B
j
and there it is now applied the same solu-
tion obtaining for each i B
j
the modified allocations.
Given a semivalue ψ Sem(G
N
) with weighting
coefficients p
n
s
, the recursively obtained numbers
p
m
s
= p
m+1
s
+ p
m+1
s+1
1 s m < n,
Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by Means of Symmetric Solutions
243
define a induced semivalue ψ
m
(Dragan, 1999) on the
space of cooperative games with m players. Adding
the own semivalue, the family of induced semivalues
{ψ
m
Sem(G
M
)/ 1 m n} allows us to define the
concept of semivalue modified for games with coali-
tion structure (Amer and Gim
´
enez, 2003) following
the same procedure as above. For a player i belongs
to coalition block B
j
the modified allocation has by
expression
ψ
i
[v;B] =
SB
j
\{i}
T M\{ j}
p
b
j
s+1
p
m
t+1
h
v
[
tT
B
t
S {i}
v
[
tT
B
t
S
i
.
(4)
For the extreme coalition structures, individual
blocks and grand coalition, the modified allocations
agree with the allocation by the initial semivalue.
Also, the allocations by modified semivalues can be
computed by means of a product of matrices, once
a reference system of binomial semivalues has been
chosen:
ψ
i
[v;B] = Λ
t
A(i) Λ. (5)
Matrix Λ is like in expression (3). The terms
a
pq
(i), 1 p,q n, of matrix A(i) can be obtained
by means of the following rules:
(i) Obtain the MLE f
v
= f
v
(x
1
,..., x
n
) of game v.
(ii) For each t M, t 6= j, and each m B
t
replace
the variable x
m
by y
t
. Thus, a new function of the
variables x
k
, y
t
for k B
j
and t M \{ j} is obtained.
(iii) In the above function, reduce all exponents
that appear in y
t
to 1, that is, replace y
r
t
(r > 1) by y
t
,
obtaining another multilinear function g
j
(x
k
,y
t
) k
B
j
and t M \ { j}.
(iv) Calculate the derivative of the function g
j
with
respect to variable x
i
.
(v) Replace each x
k
with α
p
and each y
t
with α
q
.
Then,
a
pq
(i) =
g
j
x
i
(α
p
,α
q
) for 1 p,q n. (6)
2.3 Separability in Cooperative Games
We say that two cooperative games v,v
0
G
N
are sep-
arable by a solution ψ on G
N
if ψ[v] 6= ψ[v
0
] for v 6= v
0
.
When we study separability between games accord-
ing to semivalues, we can only consider separability
from the null game, since these solutions verify lin-
earity property.
For each G
N
, the linear subspace of all cooperative
games inseparable by semivalues from the null game
is called in (Amer et al., 2003) shared kernel C
N
. It
is proven that the dimension of C
N
is 2
n
n
2
+ n 2,
since games in C
N
have to satisfy conditions:
S3i,|S|=s
v(S) = 0 for all i N and 1 s n. (7)
Grouping these conditions according to coalition
sizes, the freedom degrees for each s with 2 s
n2 are
n
s
n, whereas v(S) = 0 for |S| = 1, n1, n.
This way, the dimension of C
N
is 2
n
n
2
+ n 2 for
|N| = n 2 and C
N
= {0} if |N| = 2, 3.
In game spaces G
N
with cardinality |N| 4, for a
given coalition S N and players i, j S and k, l
N \ S, we define the commutation game v
S,i, j,k,l
as
v
S,i, j,k,l
= 1
S
+ 1
S∪{k,l}\{i, j}
1
S∪{k}\{i}
1
S∪{l}\{ j}
,
(8)
where 1
S
is the unity game in G
N
(1
S
(S) = 1 and
1
S
(T ) = 1 otherwise). If v G
N
is a commutation
game, then v C
N
. In (Amer et al., 2003), it is
proven that the shared kernel is spanned by commuta-
tion games. Since each commutation game takes non
null values uniquely on coalitions of a single size, the
number of selected games in the proof of this property
is
n
s
n for coalitions S with 2 s n 2 (|S| = s).
3 COMMUTATION GAMES AND
COALITION STRUCTURES
Let us remember that with C
N
we denote the linear
subspace of all cooperative games in G
N
inseparable
from the null game by semivalues.
Proposition 3.1. Let f
v
= f
v
(x
1
,x
2
,..., x
n
) be the
MLE of game v G
N
.
v C
N
f
v
(α) = 0 α [0,1], α = (α, . ..,α).
Proof. If v C
N
, then ψ[v] = 0 ψ Sem(G
N
).
In particular, for all binomial semivalue ψ
α
with α
[0,1], ψ
α
[v] = f
v
(α) = 0 where α = (α,α,...,α).
Conversely, since n binomial semivalues form
a reference system in Sem(G
N
), every semivalue
ψ Sem(G
N
) can uniquely be written like ψ =
n
j=1
λ
j
ψ
α
j
with α
j
[0, 1] for 1 j n. Then,
ψ[v] =
n
j=1
λ
j
ψ
α
j
[v] =
n
j=1
λ
j
f
v
(α
j
) = 0
and game v belongs to the shared kernel C
N
.
Example. Let N = {i, j, k,l} be the set of players.
For cooperative games with four players the coalition
S in the commutation games is only composed by two
players. For short, when S = {i, j} we write the com-
mutation game v
S,i, j,k,l
as v
i, j,k,l
, i. e.,
v
i, j,k,l
= 1
{i, j}
+ 1
{k,l}
1
{ j,k}
1
{i,l}
.
ICORES 2017 - 6th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
244
The MLE of this game is f
v
i, j,k,l
= x
i
x
j
+x
k
x
l
x
j
x
k
x
i
x
l
. It is easy to see that f
v
i, j,k,l
(α) = 0 α [0,1],
α = (α, α, α, α).
Definition 3.2. We say that a cooperative game v
G
N
is inseparable from the null game by semivalues
modified for games with coalition structure if and only
if ψ[v; B] = 0 for every semivalue ψ on G
N
and every
coalition structure B in N
The above definition introduces our central con-
cept of separability between games by modified semi-
values; linearity of these solutions allows us to reduce
the problem to separability from the null game. Now,
the commutation games that give the solution to the
problem of separability by semivalues, offer a differ-
ent answer according to the cardinality of the player
set.
Proposition 3.3. Let G
N
be the vector space of coop-
erative games with four players, |N| = 4. Condition
of inseparable by semivalues is equivalent to condi-
tion of inseparable by semivalues modified for games
with coalition structure.
Proof. For case |N| = 4, the shared kernel C
N
has
dimension 2. According to development in (Amer
et al., 2003), a basis for C
N
is formed by commutation
games v
1,4,3,2
and v
2,4,3,1
. For the commutation games
in a basis of C
N
, we will prove that condition of insep-
arability from the null game by semivalues extends
to condition of inseparability from the null game by
modified semivalues. For the remaining games in C
N
,
the property is verified by linearity.
We consider, for example, game v
2,4,3,1
and simul-
taneously all possible types of coalition structures in
N = {1, 2, 3, 4}. (a) Four individual blocks. (b) One
bipersonal block where game v
2,4,3,1
takes non-null
value and two individual blocks. (c) Like in (b) but
taking null value. (d) Two bipersonal blocks where
game v
2,4,3,1
takes non-null values. (e) Like in (d) but
taking null values. (f) One coalition block with three
players. (g) Only one coalition block with four play-
ers.
In cases (a) and (g), both allocations coincide:
ψ[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = ψ[v
2,4,3,1
] = 0 ψ Sem(G
N
), B =
{{1},{2}, {3}, {4}} or B = {{1,2,3,4}}.
From now, we will use the MLE f
v
2,4,3,1
= x
2
x
4
+
x
1
x
3
x
3
x
4
x
1
x
2
.
Case (b). We consider, for instance, coalition
structure B = {{1,2},{3},{4}}. According to rules
that lead to coefficients in expression (6) for obtaining
value ψ
1
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] by means of a product of matrices
as in (5), we first determine modified MLE g
1
:
g
1
(x
1
,x
2
,y
2
,y
3
) = x
2
y
3
+ x
1
y
2
y
2
y
3
x
1
x
2
;
g
1
x
1
= y
2
x
2
a
pq
(1) =
g
1
x
1
(α
p
,α
q
) = α
q
α
p
for 1 p, q 4.
Written any semivalue ψ as linear combination of
four different binomial semivalues, we can conclude
that
ψ
1
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = Λ
t
A(1) Λ = 0 ψ Sem(G
N
),
since, in this case, matrix A(1) satisfies a
pq
(1) =
a
qp
(1) for 1 p, q 4. In a similar way,
ψ
2
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = 0 ψ Sem(G
N
).
Now, for obtaining value ψ
3
[v
2,4,3,1
;B], we deter-
mine modified MLE g
2
:
g
2
(y
1
,x
3
,y
3
) = y
1
y
3
+ y
1
x
3
x
3
y
3
y
1
;
g
2
x
3
= y
1
y
3
a
pq
(3) =
g
2
x
3
(α
p
,α
q
) = 0
for 1 p, q 4.
Then ψ
3
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = 0 and, also, ψ
4
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] =
0.
Case (c). Possible coalition structure B =
{{1,4}, {2}, {3}}.
g
1
(x
1
,x
4
,y
2
,y
3
) = y
2
x
4
+ x
1
y
3
y
3
x
4
x
1
y
2
;
g
1
x
1
= y
3
y
2
a
pq
(1) =
g
1
x
1
(α
p
,α
q
) = 0
for 1 p, q 4.
Consequently, ψ
1
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = 0. In a similar way,
ψ
4
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = 0 and ψ
2
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = ψ
3
[v
2,4,3,1
;B] =
0.
Similar manipulations of MLE f
v
2,4,3,1
in cases
(d), (e) and (g) give rise to the same conclusion
ψ[v
2,4,3,1
;B] = 0.
Conversely, if a game is inseparable from the null
game by modified semivalues, in particular, it is in-
separable from the null game by semivalues. It suf-
fices to consider the coalition structure formed by in-
dividual blocks.
Proposition 3.4. For vector spaces of cooperative
games G
N
with five or more players, every commu-
tation game is separable from the null game by semi-
values modified for games with coalition structure.
Proof. In G
N
with |N| 5, the commuta-
tion gamev
S,i, j,k,l
= 1
S
+ 1
S∪{k,l}\{i, j}
1
S∪{k}\{i}
1
S∪{l}\{ j}
, with i, j S and k,l N \ S, has by MLE
f
v
S,i, j,k,l
= [x
i
x
j
+ x
k
x
l
x
j
x
k
x
i
x
l
]
pS\{i, j}
x
p
qN\(S∪{k,l})
(1 x
q
).
For coalitions S with 2 |S| < n2, we con-
sider coalition structure B
S
= {S,N \S}. The modified
MLE g
1
for players in block S is
g
1
= x
i
x
j
(1 y
2
)
pS\{i, j}
x
p
Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by Means of Symmetric Solutions
245
and
g
1
x
i
= x
j
(1 y
2
)
pS\{i, j}
x
p
,
where N \ (S {k,l}) 6=
/
0 since |S| < n2.
Then, modified Banzhaf value β separates game
v
S,i, j,k,l
, 2 |S| < n2, from the null game:
β
i
[v
S,i, j,k,l
;B
S
] =
g
1
x
i
(1/2,1/2) =
1
2
s
6= 0.
For case |S| = n2, S = N \{k, l} and the MLE is
f
v
N\{k,l},i, j,k,l
= [x
i
x
j
+ x
k
x
l
x
j
x
k
x
i
x
l
]
pN\{i, j,k,l}
x
p
.
Now, we consider coalition structure B
N\{k,l}
= {N \
{k, l},{k, l}} and we obtain the modified MLE g
1
for
players in block N \ {k,l}:
g
1
= [x
i
x
j
+ y
2
x
j
y
2
x
i
y
2
]
pN\{i, j,k,l}
x
p
,
where N \ {i, j,k,l} 6=
/
0 since |N| 5. Let h be
a player in N \ {i, j, k,l}. Again, modified Banzhaf
value β separates game v
N\{k,l},i, j,k,l
from the null
game:
g
1
x
h
= [x
i
x
j
+ y
2
x
j
y
2
x
i
y
2
]
pN\{h,i, j,k,l}
x
p
and
β
h
[v
N\{k,l},i, j,k,l
;B
N\{k,l}
] =
g
1
x
h
(1/2,1/2) =
1
2
n3
6= 0.
4 SUFFICIENT CONDITIONS OF
SEPARABILITY
For games with five or more players, the commuta-
tion games are not a solution for the problem of in-
separability by semivalues modified for games with
coalition structure. In this section we provide two
sufficient conditions of separability, that is, two nec-
essary conditions of inseparability from the null game
by modified semivalues.
Proposition 4.1. Let us consider vector spaces of co-
operative games G
N
with |N| 4. If there exists a
coalition S with v(S) 6= v(N \ S), then game v is sep-
arable from the null game by semivalues modified for
games with coalition structure.
Proof. Let us suppose S
0
a coalition with smallest
size that verifies v(S
0
) 6= v(N \ S
0
). If |S
0
| = 1, game
v is separable from the null game by semivalues and
also by modified semivalues. We can consider that
|S
0
| = s
0
2 and s
0
n/2. Then, the MLE of game v
can be written as
f
v
=
S:2≤|S|≤s
0
h
iS
x
i
jN\S
(1 x
j
)v(S)+
iN\S
x
i
jS
(1 x
j
)v(N \ S)
i
+
S:s
0
<|S|<ns
0
iS
x
i
jN\S
(1 x
j
)v(S).
Now, we choose the coalition structure B
S
0
=
{S
0
,N \ S
0
}. In such a case, the modified MLE g
1
for
players in coalition block S
0
has by expression
g
1
=
SS
0
,s2
h
(1 y
2
)
iS
x
i
jS
0
\S
(1 x
j
)+
y
2
iS
0
\S
x
i
jS
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S)+
(1 y
2
)
iS
0
x
i
v(S
0
) +y
2
jS
0
(1 x
j
)v(N\S
0
),
because terms for coalitions S containing elements as
much in S
0
as in N \S
0
vanish in MLE g
1
. If k is a
player in S
0
,
g
1
x
k
=
SS
0
,s2, S3k
h
(1 y
2
)
iS\{k}
x
i
jS
0
\S
(1 x
j
)
y
2
iS
0
\S
x
i
jS\{k}
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S)+
SS
0
,s2, S63k
h
(1 y
2
)
iS
x
i
jS
0
\(S∪{k})
(1 x
j
)+
y
2
iS
0
\(S∪{k})
x
i
jS
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S)+
+ (1 y
2
)
iS
0
\{k}
x
i
v(S
0
) y
2
jS
0
\{k}
(1 x
j
)v(N\S
0
).
Then
g
1
x
k
(1/2,1/2) =
1
2
s
0
v(S
0
) v(N\S
0
)
and the modified Banzhaf value β separates game v
from the null game:
β
k
[v;B
S
0
] =
g
1
x
k
(1/2,1/2) 6= 0 for k S
0
.
Proposition 4.2. For spaces of cooperative games
G
N
with |N| 6, let us consider a game v that sat-
isfies v(S) = v(N \ S) S N and v({i}) = 0 i N.
If there exists a coalition S with
v(S) 6=
T S, |T |=2
v(T ) and 3 |S| n/2, (9)
then game v is separable from the null game by semi-
values modified for games with coalition structure.
ICORES 2017 - 6th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
246
Proof. The MLE of game v that satisfies the two
first conditions of the statement can be written as
f
v
=
S: 2≤|S|<n/2
h
iS
x
i
jN\S
(1 x
j
) +
iN\S
x
i
jS
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S)+
S: |S|=n/2
iS
x
i
jN\S
(1 x
j
)v(S),
(10)
where the second sum only appears in case n even
number. Let us suppose S
0
a coalition with smallest
size that verifies (9) for |S
0
| < n/2. In such a case, we
choose coalition structure B
S
0
= {S
0
,N \ S
0
} and write
modified MLE g
1
for players in coalition block S
0
:
g
1
=
SS
0
,2s<s
0
h
(1 y
2
)
iS
x
i
jS
0
\S
(1 x
j
)+
y
2
iS
0
\S
x
i
jS
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S)+
h
(1 y
2
)
iS
0
x
i
+ y
2
jS
0
(1 x
j
)
i
v(S
0
).
Next, we consider a player j
1
in block S
0
, compute
the partial derivative of MLE g
1
with respect to vari-
able x
j
1
and replace all variables by generic value α
grouping the sums as follows:
g
1
x
j
1
(α,α) =
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=2
α(1 α)
s
0
1
α
s
0
1
(1 α)
v(S)+
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,2<s<s
0
α
s1
(1 α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
v(S)+
SS
0
,S63 j
1
,2s<s
0
1
α
s
0
s
(1 α)
s
α
s
(1 α)
s
0
s
]v(S)+
α(1 α)
s
0
1
α
s
0
1
(1 α)
v(S
0
\{ j
1
}) v(S
0
)
.
All terms for coalitions S with S 63 j
1
and 2 s <
s
0
1 can be written by means of coalitions T with
T 3 j
1
and 3 t < s
0
. Then,
g
1
x
j
1
(α,α) = α (1 α)
(1 α)
s
0
2
α
s
0
2
]
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=2
v(S) + v(S
0
\{ j
1
}) v(S
0
)
o
+
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,2<s<s
0
α
s1
(1 α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
v(S)+
T S
0
,T 3 j
1
,2<t<s
0
α
s
0
t+1
(1 α)
t1
α
t1
(1 α)
s
0
t+1
v(T \{ j
1
}).
We shorten polynomial (1 α)
s
0
2
α
s
0
2
by
means of p
s
0
(α) and write v(S
0
\{ j
1
}) as a sum of all
values on contained bipersonal coalitions:
g
1
x
j
1
(α,α) = α (1 α)p
s
0
(α)
h
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=2
v(S)+
T S
0
\{ j
1
},|T |=2
v(T ) v(S
0
)
i
+
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,2<s<s
0
α
s1
(1 α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
v(S) v(S\{ j
1
})
.
(11)
It is possible to find coalitions S with S S
0
, S 3 j
1
and 2 < s < s
0
only in case s
0
4. Then, the last sum
in the above expression can be written as
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,3s<1+s
0
/2
α
s1
(1 α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
v(S) v(S\{ j
1
})
+
T S
0
,T 3 j
1
,1+s
0
/2<ts
0
1
α
t1
(1 α)
s
0
t+1
α
s
0
t+1
(1 α)
t1
v(T ) v(T \{ j
1
})
,
where case s = 1 + s
0
/2 is not considered, since only
for s
0
even number, cardinality of S can take value
s = 1 + s
0
/2 but, in this case, coefficient α
s1
(1
α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
vanish. In the above
sums, we can identify coalitions S for 3 s < 1+s
0
/2
with coalitions T for 1 + s
0
/2 < t s
0
1 by means
relation t = s
0
s + 2. Then, both sums reduce to
3s<1+s
0
/2
α
s1
(1 α)
s
0
s+1
α
s
0
s+1
(1 α)
s1
n
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=s
v(S) v(S\{ j
1
})
T S
0
,T 3 j
1
,|T |=s
0
s+2
v(T ) v(T \{ j
1
})
o
.
Let us suppose that S
0
= { j
1
, j
2
,. . . , j
s
0
}. For a
given cardinality s with 3 s < 1 + s
0
/2, the last dif-
ference of sums vanish, because it can be written as
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=s
h
PS,|P|=2
v(P)
QS\{ j
1
},|Q|=2
v(Q)
i
T S
0
,T 3 j
1
,|T |=s
0
s+2
h
PT,|P|=2
v(P)
QT \{ j
1
},|Q|=2
v(Q)
i
=
SS
0
,S3 j
1
,|S|=s
h
PS,P3 j
1
,|P|=2
v(P)
i
T S
0
,T 3 j
1
,|T |=s
0
s+2
h
PT,P3 j
1
,|P|=2
v(P)
i
=
Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by Means of Symmetric Solutions
247
s
0
i=2
h
s
0
2
s 2
s
0
2
s
0
s
i
v({ j
1
, j
i
}) = 0.
Thus, from expression (11), we can write the mod-
ified binomial semivalue ψ
α
for player j
1
S
0
as
(ψ
α
)
j
1
[v;B
S
0
] =
g
1
x
j
1
(α,α) =
α(1 α)p
s
0
(α)
h
T S
0
,|T |=2
v(T ) v(S
0
)
i
.
Since α = 1/2 is the unique real zero of poly-
nomial p
s
0
for values s
0
3 and game v satisfies
inequality (9) for coalition S
0
, we conclude that
(ψ
α
)
j
1
[v;B
S
0
] 6= 0 for values α (0, 1/2) (1/2,1)
and these modified semivalues separate game v from
the null game.
It only lack to see case in which |S| = n/2 is the
smallest size of coalitions that verify (9). Here, n is
a even number and all coalitions in the second sum
of expression (10) can be grouped by pairs: S and
N \ S. The selected coalition S
0
will belong to one or
another half of coalitions with size n/2; we choose
half that contains coalition S
0
and describe the second
sum with S and N \ S, as the same way that the first
sum in (10). Then, by repeating the same procedure as
in case |S| < n/2, we arrived at the same conclusion.
5 EXPANDED COMMUTATION
GAMES
We denote with D
N
the vector subspace of all cooper-
ative games in G
N
inseparable from the null game by
semivalues modified for games with coalition struc-
ture.
Definition 5.1. In G
N
with |N| 5, we consider a
commutation game with coalition size 2, v
i, j,k,l
, k, l
N \ {i, j}. The expanded game of commutation game
v
i, j,k,l
is the sum of all commutation games in G
N
,
v
P,i, j,k,l
, with the same commuted players, i.e.,
v
e
i, j,k,l
=
P3i, j,PN\{k,l}
v
P,i, j,k,l
.
Lemma 5.2. In G
N
with |N| 5 an expanded com-
mutation game v
e
i, j,k,l
, k,l N \{i, j}, satisfies the fol-
lowing properties:
(a) v
e
i, j,k,l
(S) = v
e
i, j,k,l
(N \ S) S N;
(b) v
e
i, j,k,l
(S) =
T S, |T |=2
v
e
i, j,k,l
(T ) S N and 3
|S| |N|;
(c) its MLE is f
v
e
i, j,k,l
= x
i
x
j
+ x
k
x
l
x
j
x
k
x
i
x
l
.
Proof. It is easy to prove sections (a) and (b); it
suffices to check if players i, j, k,l belong or not to
coalitions S, since the only bipersonal coalitions that
take non-null values in game v
e
i, j,k,l
are {i, j}, {k,l},
{ j, k} and {i,l}. In order to verify section (c) we can
write MLE of game v
e
i, j,k,l
as
f
v
e
i, j,k,l
=
x
i
x
j
+ x
k
x
l
x
j
x
k
x
i
x
l
h
qN\{i, j,k,l}
(1 x
q
) + f
QN\{i, j,k,l}
1
Q
i
,
where games 1
Q
are considered in G
N\{i, j,k,l}
. Since
QN\{i, j,k,l}
1
Q
(T ) = 1 T N \ {i, j,k,l}, T 6=
/
0,
(Q 6=
/
0), its MLE equals the unity in N \ {i, j,k, l}
and section (c) follows.
Proposition 5.3. In spaces of cooperative games G
N
with |N| 5, every expanded commutation game
v
e
i, j,k,l
, k,l N \{i, j} belongs to vector subspace D
N
.
Proof. Section (c) in above Lemma proves that
MLE of expanded commutation game v
e
i, j,k,l
, k,l
N \{i, j} in G
N
with |N| 5 agrees with MLE of com-
mutation game v
i, j,k,l
in a space of cooperative games
with only four players, {i, j,k,l}.
In order to demonstrate that game v
e
i, j,k,l
, k,l
N \ {i, j}, is inseparable by modified semivalues, we
can consider that players i, j,k,l are distributed in
different coalition blocks in the same way that in
the proof of Proposition 3.3. The remaining players
N \{i, j, k,l} will be distributed in the different blocks
next to players i, j,k,l or they will form new coalition
blocks.
Since variables that correspond to players in N \
{i, j,k,l} does not appear in the MLE of game v
e
i, j,k,l
,
when we compute allocations for players i, j,k,l by
means of a product of matrices as in (5), we ob-
tain the same result as in Proposition 3.3, that is,
ψ
p
[v
e
i, j,k,l
,B] = 0 for p = i, j,k, l, ψ Sem(G
N
), B
coalition structure in N.
For the remaining players, ψ
q
[v
e
i, j,k,l
,B] = 0 q
N \ {i, j, k,l}, since variable x
q
does not appear in the
MLE.
Theorem 5.4. Let us consider vector spaces of coop-
erative games G
N
with five or more players, |N| 5.
Then,
(a) dim D
N
=
n
2
n;
(b) the vector subspace D
N
is spanned by expanded
of commutation games with coalition size 2.
Proof. We can see in (Amer et al., 2003) that the
shared kernel C
N
for |N| 4 is spanned by 2
n
n
2
+
n 2 commutation games whose coalitions with non-
null value vary from cardinality s = 2 to n 2. We
choose the
n
2
n commutation games with coalition
ICORES 2017 - 6th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
248
size 2. As they are linearly independent in G
N
, its
expanded games are also linearly independent and, by
above Proposition, inseparable from the null game by
modified semivalues. The linear subspace spanned by
these expanded commutation games is contained in
subspace D
N
for |N| 5.
In addition, as D
N
C
N
, the freedom degrees in
C
N
by a consequence of conditions (7) for coalitions
with sizes s > n/2 disappear according to necessary
condition of inseparability from the null game in D
N
:
v(S) = v(N \ S) (Proposition 4.1). Also, the free-
dom degrees for coalitions with size from s = 3 to
s = n/2 disappear according to necessary condition
v(S) =
T S, |T |=2
v(T ) S N with 3 |S| n/2
(Proposition 4.2).
Only the
n
2
n freedom degrees for coalition size
s = 2 in C
N
remain in vector subspace D
N
. Then,
the vector subspace spanned by the
n
2
n expanded
commutation games agrees with D
N
.
6 CONCLUSION
It is known that every cooperative game with two or
three players is separable from the null game by semi-
values, so that dimension for the shared kernel C
N
is
zero in cases n = 2,3. Consequently, vector subspace
D
N
is only formed by the null game in cases n = 2,3.
For games with four players, Proposition 3.3 proves
that both separability concepts coincide: D
N
= C
N
for
n = 4.
Table 1 compares dimensions of C
N
and D
N
for
cooperative games with few players.
Table 1: Dimensions of kernels according to N.
|N| = n 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
dimG
N
3 7 15 31 63 127 255
dimC
N
0 0 2 10 32 84 198
dimD
N
0 0 2 5 9 14 20
For games with five or more players, the intro-
duction of modified semivalues for games with coali-
tion structure allows us to reduce in a significant way
the dimension of the vector subspace of inseparable
games from the null game. According to the linearity
property, separability between two games is reduced
by both concepts of solution to separability of their
difference from the null game. The ability of sep-
aration by semivalues has considerably increased by
introduction of a priori coalition structures.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Research supported by grant MTM2015-66818-P
from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and FEDER.
REFERENCES
Albizuri, M. J. (2009). Generalized coalitional semivalues.
European Journal of Operational Research, 196:578–
584.
Amer, R., Derks, J., and Gim
´
enez, J. M. (2003). On cooper-
ative games, inseparable by semivalues. International
Journal of Game Theory, 32:181–188.
Amer, R. and Gim
´
enez, J. M. (2003). Modification of semi-
values for games with coalition structures. Theory and
Decision, 54:185–205.
Banzhaf, J. F. (1965). Weighted voting doesn’t work: A
mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Review, 19:317–
343.
Carreras, F., Freixas, J., and Puente, M. A. (2003). Semi-
values as power indices. European Journal of Opera-
tional Research, 149:676–687.
Carreras, F. and Gim
´
enez, J. M. (2011). Power and poten-
tial maps induced by any semivalue: Some algebraic
properties and computation by multilinear extensions.
European Journal of Operational Research, 211:148–
159.
Dragan, I. (1999). Potential and consistency for semivalues
of finite cooperative TU games. International Journal
of Mathematics, Game Theory and Algebra, 9:85–97.
Dubey, P., Neyman, A., and Weber, R. J. (1981). Value
theory without efficiency. Mathematics of Operations
Research, 6:122–128.
Gim
´
enez, J. M. and Puente, M. A. (2015). A method to
calculate generalized mixed modified semivalues: ap-
plication to the catalan parliament (legislature 2012-
2016). TOP, 23:669–684.
Owen, G. (1972). Multilinear extensions of games. Man-
agement Science, 18:64–79.
Owen, G. (1975). Multilinear extensions and the Banzhaf
value. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 22:741–
750.
Owen, G. (1977). Values of games with a priori unions. In
Essays in Mathematical Economics and Game The-
ory, pages 76–88. R. Henn and O. Moeschelin (Edi-
tors), Springer-Verlag.
Owen, G. (1981). Modification of the Banzhaf-Coleman in-
dex for games with a priori unions. In Power, Voting
and Voting Power, pages 232–238. M.J. Holler (Edi-
tor), Physica-Verlag.
Shapley, L. S. (1953). A value for n-person games. In Con-
tributions to the Theory of Games II, pages 307–317.
H.W. Kuhn and A.W. Tucker (Editors), Princeton Uni-
versity Press.
Weber, R. J. (1988). Probabilistic values for games. In The
Shapley value: Essays in honor of L.S. Shapley, pages
101–119. A.E. Roth (Editor), Cambridge University
Press.
Ability to Separate Situations with a Priori Coalition Structures by Means of Symmetric Solutions
249